Text Material Preview
Fostering product innovation: Differences between new ventures and established firms Raquel Antolín-López, José Céspedes-Lorente, Nieves García-de-Frutos, Javier Martínez-del-Río, Miguel Pérez-Valls n Universidad de Almería, Department of Economy and Business Administration, Carretera de Sacramento s/n, Almería 04120, Spain a r t i c l e i n f o Keywords: Entrepreneurship New ventures Innovation policy Product innovation Competency-based view a b s t r a c t This study combines insights from the entrepreneurship, competency-based view and innovation policy literature to analyze the relationships among different types of public incentives designed to foster innovation and product innovation at both new ventures and incumbent firms. To test our hypotheses, we ran a system of regression models on a cross-national sample comprised of 5238 firms from 29 European countries and found a different pattern for new ventures and incumbents. Our results suggest that support for attendance or participation in trade fairs and networking with other companies are the most effective methods of promoting product innovation for new ventures. However, for incumbent firms, we found that the most effective policies consisted of tax reduction for R&D expenditures and subsidies for acquiring buildings or other infrastructure(s) for innovation activities. This distinction prompts interesting insights related to theory development in research on entrepreneurship and innovation policy. & 2015 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved. 1. Introduction A growing body of research addresses the effectiveness of public support instruments designed to incentivize firm innovation (e.g., Almus and Czarnitzki, 2003; Busom, 2000; Gonzalez and Pazo, 2008). This research stream largely focuses on the effects of public innova- tion programs on firms' R&D investments (e.g., David et al., 2000; Klette et al., 2000; Lach, 2002; Wallsten, 2000) and, in particular, on whether public R&D funding has a “crowding-out” or substitution effect on private R&D investment (e.g., Aerts and Schmidt, 2008; Almus and Czarnitzki, 2003; Czarnitzki and Fier, 2002; Czarnitzki and Lopes-Bento, 2013; Yang et al., 2012). Although there are exceptions (e.g., Cappelen et al., 2012; Czarnitzki et al., 2011; Huergo andMoreno, 2014), studies have not typically examined the effectiveness of public R&D programs using output measures such as patents and product innovations; as a consequence, little remains known about how effective public policy instruments are in this regard. In addition, although policy makers have employed a variety of innovation policy instruments, a vast majority of this literature focuses narrowly on one type of R&D program. In particular, there is a need for studies that compare the effectiveness of different types of public instruments; thus, the specific impact of such instruments on firm innovation output remains unclear (e.g., Blanes and Busom, 2004; Woolley and Rottner, 2008). For example, many previous studies use the Commu- nity Innovation Survey (e.g., Aerts and Schmidt, 2008), which contains limited information in this regard. In this paper, we focus on an analysis of the differential effect of a number of public funding schemes on the innovation output of new ventures and incumbent firms. This approach is relevant because governments employ economic rationales to support innovative new ventures based on the reasoning that new ven- tures generate the most new jobs in developed economies and play a significant role in the emergence of new economic sectors (e.g., Sine and Lee, 2009). New ventures also improve resource allocation in the economy by identifying factors that established players may be blind to, such as when goods or services become unexpectedly valuable or feasible for consumers (Ireland et al., 2003). Moreover, Arrow (1962) and Nelson (1959) indicated that innovations by new ventures frequently generate positive external effects that cannot be internalized by the entrepreneurs. Public support can make a difference in a firm's early stages (Norrman, 2008). New ventures frequently fail to develop innovative ideas because they lack the appropriate assets and capabilities (Arthurs and Busenitz, 2006; Norrman and Klofsten, 2009). We contend that because new ventures may find particularly difficult to deploy, develop and combine their innovative capabilities (Alvarez and Busenitz, 2001), they can also get the maximum benefit from public instruments specifically intended to facilitate the development of such capabilities. For example, instruments intended to increase a Contents lists available at ScienceDirect journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/technovation Technovation http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 0166-4972/& 2015 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved. n Corresponding author. Tel.: þ34 950 214173; fax: þ34 950 015178. E-mail addresses: ral252@ual.es (R. Antolín-López), jcespede@ual.es (J. Céspedes-Lorente), gdn779@ual.es (N. García-de-Frutos), jamartin@ual.es (J. Martínez-del-Río), mivalls@ual.es (M. Pérez-Valls). Please cite this article as: Antolín-López, R., et al., Fostering product innovation: Differences between new ventures and established firms. Technovation (2015), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002i Technovation ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎ www.sciencedirect.com/science/journal/01664972 www.elsevier.com/locate/technovation http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 mailto:ral252@ual.es mailto:jcespede@ual.es mailto:gdn779@ual.es mailto:jamartin@ual.es mailto:mivalls@ual.es http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 https://www.researchgate.net/publication/222553561_Two_for_the_Price_of_One_Additionality_Effects_of_RD_Subsidies_A_Comparison_between_Flanders_and_Germany?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/4986917_The_Effects_of_Public_RD_Subsidies_on_Firms'_Innovation_Activities_The_Case_of_Eastern_Germany?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/222320647_Dynamic_Capabilities_and_Venture_Performance_The_Effects_of_Venture_Capitalists?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/227611654_An_Empirical_Evaluation_of_The_Effects_of_RD_Subsidies?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/222531355_Do_public_subsidies_stimulate_private_RD_spending?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/24106362_The_Simple_Economics_of_Basic_Economic_Research?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/268296462_Entrepreneurship_Policy_Public_Support_for_Technology-Based_Ventures?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== firm's contact networks may be particularly beneficial because they assist new ventures in gaining access to valuable knowledge outside of company boundaries, which is one of the most important assets involved in product innovation(Chesbrough, 2003). Although public administrations may support innovationwith many different types of instruments, the most widely used in recent years in Europe include subsidies and grants, tax incentives, financing, funding for network- ing with companies and research institutes, and facilitating informa- tion on market conditions (COM, 2009). This paper thus tackles which innovation policy instruments are better at fostering product innovation in new ventures compared with incumbents. In seeking to answer this research question, this paper makes two theoretical contributions: first, we provide new theoretical insights into the notion that innovation policy instru- ments might have different effects on new ventures than on incumbent firms. Our current understanding of the dissimilarities among policy instruments is weak. An important contribution of this paper is its focus on identifying the differences among the most common innovation policy instruments and how these instruments affect product innovation in both new ventures and incumbent firms. Second, this research links the competency-based view with entre- preneurship and innovation policy literatures to suggest that these differences involve the ability of innovation instruments to provide – or foster the development of – key competitive capabilities to firms. New ventures and incumbents are the result of a combination of a diverse bundle of capabilities and competences. Consequently, some innovation policy instruments will better fit the character- istics of new ventures, whereas other instruments will correspond better to the specificities of incumbent firms. Specifically, we suggest that funding for marketing and networking activities related to innovation are more beneficial for new ventures, whereas grants and tax reductions are more advantageous for incumbents. By exploring the effects' variations on new ventures and incum- bents, we provide new perspectives and possible explanations for the inconclusive results of previous studies regarding incentives' general effects on innovation (e.g., Cappelen et al., 2012). Studying the differentiated effect of public programs to promote innovation on entrepreneurial ventures is of practical significance for policy makers whomight otherwise fail to achieve their goals by using the wrong instrument when attempting to support innovative entre- preneurs. The conclusions obtained may help identify the unintended effects of certain programs and to interpret the observed outcomes correctly. In addition, this line of research is also valuable for manage- rial practice because it provides guidance concerning which public programs are more appropriate for new ventures and incumbents. Studying the antecedents of product innovation in new ventures is important because it represents a key dimension of entrepreneur- ship. For example, typical new venture competences, such as flex- ibility, the ability to recognize entrepreneurial opportunities or entrepreneurial alertness (Burg et al., 2012; Marion et al., 2012), may be considered complementary assets for new product develop- ment. New products may enhance firm performance for both new ventures and incumbents. However, these products are even more important for the survival of new ventures (Marion et al., 2012; Radas and Bozic, 2009) because they constitute a means of develop- ing other relevant competitive capabilities (Danneels, 2002), of gaining market share (Aspelund et al., 2005) and of earning revenues, which is particularly critical for new firms (Kleinschmidt and Cooper, 1991). New ventures are more dependent on new product develop- ment because all their products are new (Schoonhoven et al., 1990), to an extent. Conversely, incumbents can opt to cash out on their already current successful products. We empirically analyze these issues using a cross-national sample comprised of 5238 firms (new ventures and incumbents) from 29 European countries. By considering different institutional contexts, we provide a framework that governments and managers can use to design or adopt effective and specific public innovation incentive portfolios aimed at both new ventures and established firms. 2. Theoretical framework 2.1. A competency-based view of new ventures' ability to innovate The entrepreneurship literature has examined how new ventures experience specific restrictions of resources and capabilities that may limit their strategic choices when competing with established firms (Aspelund et al., 2005; Bruton and Rubanik, 2002). This initial limited endowment of assets and capabilities is frequently called “the liability of newness” because it hinders new ventures in the devel- opment of various competences and in their ability to compete and prosper (Bruton and Rubanik, 2002; Stinchcombe, 1965). We posit that the competency-based view may add theoretical insight into the understanding of how innovation policy instruments can help new ventures overcome the liability of newness and augment their abilities with respect to launching new products. The competency-based view conceptualizes firms as hetero- geneous configurations of competences and capabilities that determine how and whether value-creating strategies are imple- mented and competitive advantages realized (e.g., Prahalad and Hamel, 1990; Walsh and Linton, 2001). This perspective links a firm's internal environment to its organizational competences to predict economic performance. Organizational competences are those specific assets, knowledge, skills and capabilities embedded in the organizational structure and processes that enable the organization to develop, choose and implement value-enhancing strategies (Lado and Wilson, 1994), such as product innovation. Companies' abilities to integrate, build and reconfigure corporate- wide technologies and capabilities into core competences are difficult to imitate and provides superior value to customers (Lado and Wilson, 1994; Prahalad and Hamel, 1990). New ventures and established companies differ in the config- urations of their capabilities and competences, which impacts new product development competences. New ventures are characterized by important entrepreneurship-related capabilities, such as flex- ibility, creativity, alertness and the ability to recognize opportunities (Burg et al., 2012; Marion et al., 2012). Entrepreneurial capabilities confer new ventures with the ability to see what established players do not, such as identifying when goods or services become unexpectedly valuable to consumers or feasible to produce (Ireland et al., 2003). However, entrepreneurship research also shows that new ventures frequently lack the internal assets necessary to develop new products, such as experienced personnel (Schoonhoven et al., 1990), market and technological knowledge (Gans and Stern, 2003), marketing skills (Marion et al., 2012), social capital (Aspelund et al., 2005; Baker and Nelson, 2005), production equipment (Schoonhoven et al., 1990) and funding (Burke et al., 2010; Marion et al., 2012). In general, new ventures lack the organizational routines, skills and best practices that incumbents possess and that enable them to develop certain types of compe- titive advantages (Bruton and Rubanik, 2002). Moreover new ventures cannot afford to experiment with a variety of new ideas to the same extent as incumbents (Burg et al., 2012), and they do not possess sufficient resources to absorb product failure (Marion et al., 2012). Therefore, new ventures must cope with their initial limited endowment of assets and lack of experience and time all of them required to develop their innovation capabilities. Based on the different endowments that characterize new ventures and established companies with respect to developing product innovations (i.e., which assets and capabilities they cur- rently possess and which must be developed or acquired), public instruments designed to encourage innovation may be expected to R. Antolín-López et al. / Technovation∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎2 Please cite this article as: Antolín-López, R., et al., Fostering product innovation: Differences between new ventures and established firms. Technovation (2015), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002i http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 https://www.researchgate.net/publication/222971862_Initial_Resources'_Influence_on_New_Venture_Survival_A_Longitudinal_Study_of_New_Technology-Based_Firms?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/222971862_Initial_Resources'_Influence_on_New_Venture_Survival_A_Longitudinal_Study_of_New_Technology-Based_Firms?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/222971862_Initial_Resources'_Influence_on_New_Venture_Survival_A_Longitudinal_Study_of_New_Technology-Based_Firms?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/228316078_Creating_Something_From_Nothing_Resource_Construction_Through_Entrepreneurial_Bricolage?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/4967912_Resources_of_the_Firm_Russian_High-Technology_Start-Ups_and_Firm_Growth?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/4967912_Resources_of_the_Firm_Russian_High-Technology_Start-Ups_and_Firm_Growth?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/4967912_Resources_of_the_Firm_Russian_High-Technology_Start-Ups_and_Firm_Growth?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/232717070_Directive_Deficiencies_How_Resource_Constraints_Direct_Opportunity_Identification_in_SMEs?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/232717070_Directive_Deficiencies_How_Resource_Constraints_Direct_Opportunity_Identification_in_SMEs?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/232717070_Directive_Deficiencies_How_Resource_Constraints_Direct_Opportunity_Identification_in_SMEs?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/256921095_The_effects_of_RD_tax_credits_on_patenting_and_innovations?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/235700923_Open_Innovation_The_New_Imperative_for_Creating_and_Profiting_From_Technology?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/215915564_The_Dynamics_of_Product_Innovation_an_Firm_Competences?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/4929397_The_Product_Market_and_the_Market_for_'Ideas'_Commercialization_Strategies_for_Entrepreneurs?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/228171425_A_Model_of_Strategic_Entrepreneurship_The_Construct_and_Its_Dimensions?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/271807715_Human_Resource_Systems_and_Sustained_Competitive_Advantage_A_Competency-Based_Perspective?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/271807715_Human_Resource_Systems_and_Sustained_Competitive_Advantage_A_Competency-Based_Perspective?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/264482062_New_Product_Development_Practices_and_Early-Stage_Firms_Two_In-Depth_Case_Studies?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/264482062_New_Product_Development_Practices_and_Early-Stage_Firms_Two_In-Depth_Case_Studies?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/264482062_New_Product_Development_Practices_and_Early-Stage_Firms_Two_In-Depth_Case_Studies?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/227000462_The_Core_Competence_of_Corporation?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/273075728_Speeding_Product_to_Market_Waiting_Time_to_First_Product_Introduction_in_New_Firms?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/273075728_Speeding_Product_to_Market_Waiting_Time_to_First_Product_Introduction_in_New_Firms?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/273075728_Speeding_Product_to_Market_Waiting_Time_to_First_Product_Introduction_in_New_Firms?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/242348803_Social_Structure_and_Organizations?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== have different effects on new ventures and established companies. From a competency-based view perspective, the effect of public policy instruments can be understood in terms of the assets and capabilities they provide to such companies and how these assets and capabilities fit such companies' needs to develop product innovation. Because there are many different types of public incentives implemented to encourage innovation in current econo- mies that differ in the capabilities and competences they provide – or help to develop –, we posit that some types of instruments would more suitable than others to supplement the capabilities and competences portfolios of new ventures compared with established companies todevelop product innovations. Therefore, we offer a competency based-view of how different innovation policy instru- ments assist new ventures to overcome the liability of newness when developing new products, and how existing types of public instruments affect product innovation development differently in new ventures compared with incumbents. 2.2. Public support for innovation as a method of overcoming the effects of the liability of newness on new product development 2.2.1. Public subsidy programs Subsidies are common innovation policy instruments that con- sist of economic grants that are not repaid. Keizer et al. (2002) found that success in obtaining subsidies for innovation requires considerable and persistent effort. The lengthy and intricate process of applying for a subsidy typically involves elaborating complex research project and budgetary proposals, meeting standards of quality, passing a number of technical reviews and eventually satisfying public economic conditions and controls regarding expenses related to the project. When managing these complex processes, new ventures suffer from a lack of personnel who possess these specific skills and experience. Additionally, they are less likely to have developed the routines and best practices (i.e., the competence) required to succeed in the calls for projects, such as those regarding how to structure a project, how to write a proposal or how to address and communicate with reviewers, which are typically acquired through “learning-by-doing” processes. Conver- sely, even if they are small or medium-sized enterprises (SMEs), innovative incumbents are more likely to be experienced in these types of processes and to have had the time required to develop the best practices and skills for handling the relevant submission processes. Consequently, in spite of the greater effort that new ventures devoted when applying for similar projects, this type of process may result less efficient for new ventures. In addition, public calls for projects typically have specific goals to promote certain technologies or strategic sectors (Blanes and Busom, 2004; Santamaria et al., 2010). According to Nelson (1959), govern- ments tend to support projects with the largest gaps between social and private return (e.g., basic research), whereas private companies are more likely to invest in R&D projects with the highest rates of private return (e.g., applied research). Thus, firms must frequently face a trade-off between a project that maximizes future market success and one that maximizes public support. Companies fre- quently encounter problems during the process and are forced to make impromptu decisions to satisfy both public grant conditions and technical or marketing requirements. This status quo and decisions may ultimately challenge the technical viability of research projects, and some already planned new products's launching may even result a failure. Nonetheless, established firms' experience and resources play an important role to handle this trade-off successfully. 2.2.2. Tax incentives Through tax incentives, firms can deduct some of the resources invested in innovation from the total amount of taxes that the company must pay at the end of the fiscal year. This reduces the costs of innovation, which causes managers to perceive a lower risk in deciding to invest in new product development. This perception causes companies to adopt innovative strategies more frequently and invest more resources in R&D (Berube and Mohnen, 2009; Czarnitzki et al., 2011; Yang et al., 2012). Peneder (2008) notes that tax reductions are typically related to corporate income taxes and thus act only as incentives for compa- nies that are profitable. In the EU, regulations frequently allow tax reductions to be carried forward for a certain number of years until the firm can obtain benefits from the tax incentives. However, entrepreneurial firms frequently suffer losses during their initial years and only obtain returns on the investments in the long term (Oakey, 2003; Storey and Tether, 1998). The factors underlying this circumstance include the following: the time required to access new markets (Norrman and Klofsten, 2009), the regulatory and technical entry barriers commonly faced by startups (Storey and Tether, 1998), and their lack of economies of scale. Thus, the incentive's effect may be delayed for most new ventures, which might result in a loss of part of its effect. Therefore, new ventures are less likely to take advantage of the positive impact of these public mechanisms (Peneder, 2008) because they frequently do not earn sufficient taxable profits (Hall and van Reenen, 2000). Additionally, because of their size and limited financial resources, new ventures might find difficult to invest the max- imum amount allowed for tax reduction while established firms are less likely to face this type of restriction. Consequently, this incentive results particularly useful for incumbents. 2.2.3. Public support for networking Being up-to-date on many diverse, complex and changing tech- nologies are particularly difficult for new ventures because of their lack of resources, experience and limited technical competences (Bruton and Rubanik, 2002). In addition, startups possess more limited networks of contacts (Aspelund et al., 2005; Zhang and Li, 2010). Accordingly, new ventures possess only limited internal knowledge and tend to narrow their external search scope by relying exclusively upon their immediate personal networks to discover and recognize opportunities (Baker and Nelson, 2005). One strategy startups can use to overcome this constraint involves focusing on what they do best while acquiring and co-developing knowledge within a widespread network of firms (Nelson, 1959). Therefore, public support for coop- eration and networking can be particularly valuable to new ventures that are engaged in developing innovative projects. Cooperation can be a means of skipping the problem of innovation indivisibility and risk (Arrow, 1962). Because only fully developed innovations can be launched in the market, R&D investment pays off only when the entire investment is made. Cooperation allows dividing a project into parts and avoiding costly investment in laboratories, equipment and/or experts (Sakakibara, 1997, 2002). R&D collaboration also allows companies to reduce risk by investing only a small part of the total amount required to develop a new technology and diversify new product portfolios (Arrow, 1962) and by avoiding research duplication and duplicative final products on the market. This risk reduction component is particularly critical for new ventures that are characterized by intrinsically high levels of risk. Interfirm networks also boost firm innovativeness by providing access to partners' technological know-how, salient market knowl- edge and complementary capabilities that help improve new ventures' skill base (Zahra and Filatotchev, 2004). Collaboration with a knowledgeable partner can accelerate “learning by doing” processes and allow innovative capabilities to be perfected. The open innovation literature (Chesbrough, 2003) suggests that innovation-related cooperation is also beneficial for incumbents. R. Antolín-López et al. / Technovation ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎ 3 Please cite this article as: Antolín-López, R., et al., Fostering product innovation: Differences between new ventures and established firms. Technovation (2015), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002i http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 https://www.researchgate.net/publication/222971862_Initial_Resources'_Influence_on_New_Venture_Survival_A_Longitudinal_Study_of_New_Technology-Based_Firms?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/228316078_Creating_Something_From_Nothing_Resource_Construction_Through_Entrepreneurial_Bricolage?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ==https://www.researchgate.net/publication/4967912_Resources_of_the_Firm_Russian_High-Technology_Start-Ups_and_Firm_Growth?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/235700923_Open_Innovation_The_New_Imperative_for_Creating_and_Profiting_From_Technology?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/4928879_'How_Effective_Are_Fiscal_Incentives_for_RD_A_Review_of_the_Evidence'?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/222316413_Explaining_Innovative_Efforts_of_SMEs_An_Exploratory_Survey_Among_SMEs_in_the_Mechanical_and_Electrical_Engineering_Sector_in_Netherlands?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/24106362_The_Simple_Economics_of_Basic_Economic_Research?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/247511598_Funding_innovation_and_growth_in_UK_new_technology-based_firms_Some_observations_on_contributions_from_the_public_and_private_sectors?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/222407338_The_problem_of_private_under-investment_in_innovation_A_policy_mind_map?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/222407338_The_problem_of_private_under-investment_in_innovation_A_policy_mind_map?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/229466418_Heterogeneity_of_Firm_Capabilities_and_Cooperative_Research_and_Development_An_Empirical_Examination_of_Motives?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/227375449_Governance_of_the_Entrepreneurial_Threshold_Firm_A_Knowledge-Based_Perspective?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/227516623_Innovation_Search_of_New_Ventures_in_a_Technology_Cluster_The_Role_of_Ties_with_Service_Intermediaries?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== However, such cooperation may not be as important for established companies because their resources are not as limited. Under certain circumstances, firms may prefer to conduct research in-house to gain control of the research process and ensure ownership of the results (Sakakibara, 2002). Indeed, most established firms develop new products without entering into innovation cooperative arrangements with other organizations (Tether, 2002). Although some scholars claim that universities rarely develop market-ready innovations (e.g., Radas and Bozic, 2009; Tether and Tajar, 2008b), networking with universities and research centers provides access to valuable and specialized knowledge that is not always available in markets at low cost and with low risk (Tether, 2002). Therefore, companies with scant R&D capabilities innovate more effectively through university and research center collabora- tion (Keizer et al., 2002; Sakakibara, 2002). 2.2.4. Marketing information Marketing capabilities have been considered to be a comple- mentary asset to new product innovation (Teece, 1986). Given the paramount importance of the fit between new product features and market needs, reliance on elaborate, abundant and accurate mar- keting information appears to be critical to new product success. Startups typically lack the marketing skills of incumbents (Marion et al., 2012), and improving these skills can have a significant impact on the level of new product success. New ventures often have scant information on market conditions, regulatory entry barriers (Norrman, 2008), competition rules, industry recipes (Zahra and Filatotchev, 2004) and customer needs (Burke et al., 2010). These information asymmetries crop up because market data and informa- tion can be gathered through research but “also arise in the daily course of economic life as a by-product of other economic activities” (Arrow, 1962, 614). Therefore, market information is not perfectly distributed. Because incumbents have more experience and market knowledge than newcomers, public programs providing advice and information on market conditions should reduce the higher rates of uncertainty associated with product innovation in new ventures and increase the success rate of their new products (Arrow, 1962). Conversely, incumbents have typically previously tested their pro- ducts in the market and are more experienced with regard to marketing processes. Consequently, they typically have more polished marketing capabilities compared with new ventures. Public policies may also facilitate and fund attendance at trade fairs, which constitute a feasible manner of obtaining marketing information and acquiring social capital in the form of contacts with potential customers and suppliers. New ventures can use fairs to identify possible partners along the value chain – a process that is both difficult for and valuable to new ventures (Gans and Stern, 2003; Gilsing et al., 2010) – and to improve their opportu- nity recognition capabilities (Ozgen and Baron, 2007). Moreover, according to the “open innovation” paradigm (Chesbrough, 2003), social capital is at the heart of innovation, and both internal and external ideas (originating from suppliers, customers, and others) are key factors in the innovation process. However, startups have weaker external contacts (Zhang and Li, 2010) and no stable relationships with suppliers and customers (Bruton and Rubanik, 2002), whereas incumbents tend to possess a wider range of contacts and an established value chain. Therefore, because of their potential for building social networks, trade fairs are expected to have a positive impact on the innovative efforts of new ventures (Ozgen and Baron, 2007). 2.2.5. Support for R&D project financing Most new ventures begin with very limited financial resources (e.g., Burke et al., 2010; Marion et al., 2012), and this limitation constitutes one of their primary constraints (e.g., Schoonhoven et al., 1990). However, accessing suitable financial resources and loans is of paramount importance to excel in the new product development process (Martin and Scott, 2000) because it typically requires costly and time-consuming investments in R&D facilities and skilled R&D human capital. Finding the optimal financing for their R&D projects is comparatively more difficult for new ventures because of the higher levels of perceived uncertainty and risk associated with them (Arthurs and Busenitz, 2006; Oakey, 2003). Resource limitations “are likely to make underinvestment in risky enterprises more likely than the opposite” (Arrow, 1962, 611), and these hinder startups' ability to attract new investors and obtain loans from banks. Therefore, direct support in financing innovation projects under favorable conditions – such as lower (or a lack of) enforcement mechanisms and interest rates – might be of particularinterest to new ventures. Established firms typically have lengthier and more stable relation- ships with bankers and investors. Because of their proven performance record and existing accounting information, financial institutions can track their performance and evolution over several years. Moreover, established companies generally have cash flows that are superior to those of new ventures (Schoonhoven et al., 1990); thus, as a consequence, access to financial resources is less problematic for established companies (Bruton et al., 2010). For their part, new ventures have not had time to demonstrate that they are viable companies, and their performance records are limited or nonexistent (Bruton et al., 2010; Zhang and Li, 2010), which derives in a more difficult, costly and risky success for new ventures' prospective projections. As a result, banks and investors perceive larger informa- tion asymmetries that drive them to impose stricter enforcement mechanisms on new ventures (Bosse, 2009), which means that the entrepreneur must assume additional costs and/or higher risks. More- over, banks typically offer rigid standard conditions to new ventures but are more open to negotiating conditions with incumbents. Public support mechanisms for financing innovation are fre- quently less exigent and complex compared with public subsidies. Although firms must typically undergo similar processes before receiving funds, public loans frequently require the firm to dedicate fewer resources to the control and ex post assessment of the project. Since firms are compelled to repay the loan received, public administrations frequently do not develop such thoroughly technical and economic projects' assessments. After this argumentation, we might conclude that the impact of public support policies follows a different pattern for new ven- tures and for established firms. Therefore, we posit the following: Hypothesis 1. For new ventures, public support incentives that are more relevant to foster product innovations are (1a) Public policies supporting networking and cooperation, (1b) Public policies facilitat- ing the obtainment of marketing information and contacts and (1c) Public support for financing innovation projects. Hypothesis 2. For established firms, public support incentives that are more relevant to foster product innovations are (2a) Public subsidy programs and (2b) Tax reductions for R&D expenditures 3. Methods 3.1. Sample The dataset used in this study covers a sample of companies with 20 or more employees operating within one of the 27 Member States of the EU, Switzerland or Norway. Data were gathered from the “Eurobarometer No. 215” survey. This survey is part of the Innobarometers series, which is regularly conducted at the request of the European Commission to address diverse topics related to innovation in European companies. Access to this cross-national database was provided by the Central Archive for R. Antolín-López et al. / Technovation ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎4 Please cite this article as: Antolín-López, R., et al., Fostering product innovation: Differences between new ventures and established firms. Technovation (2015), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002i http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 https://www.researchgate.net/publication/24017049_Bundling_governance_mechanisms_to_efficiently_organize_small_firm_loans?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/228269973_Institutional_Theory_and_Entrepreneurship_Where_Are_We_Now_and_Where_Do_We_Need_to_Move_in_the_Future?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/228269973_Institutional_Theory_and_Entrepreneurship_Where_Are_We_Now_and_Where_Do_We_Need_to_Move_in_the_Future?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/46540418_The_Multiple_Effects_of_Business_Planning_on_New_Venture_Performance?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/46540418_The_Multiple_Effects_of_Business_Planning_on_New_Venture_Performance?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/235700923_Open_Innovation_The_New_Imperative_for_Creating_and_Profiting_From_Technology?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/222316413_Explaining_Innovative_Efforts_of_SMEs_An_Exploratory_Survey_Among_SMEs_in_the_Mechanical_and_Electrical_Engineering_Sector_in_Netherlands?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/264482062_New_Product_Development_Practices_and_Early-Stage_Firms_Two_In-Depth_Case_Studies?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/268296462_Entrepreneurship_Policy_Public_Support_for_Technology-Based_Ventures?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/222749119_Social_Sources_of_Information_in_Opportunity_Recognition_Effects_of_Mentors_Industry_Networks_and_Professional_Forum?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/222749119_Social_Sources_of_Information_in_Opportunity_Recognition_Effects_of_Mentors_Industry_Networks_and_Professional_Forum?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/227541279_Formation_of_RD_Consortia_Industry_and_Company_Effects?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/227541279_Formation_of_RD_Consortia_Industry_and_Company_Effects?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/273075728_Speeding_Product_to_Market_Waiting_Time_to_First_Product_Introduction_in_New_Firms?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/222446198_Profiting_From_Technological_Innovation_Implication_for_Integration_Collaboration_Licensing_and_Public_Policy?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/223453074_Who_Co-Operates_for_Innovation_and_Why_-_An_Empirical_Analysis?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== https://www.researchgate.net/publication/227516623_Innovation_Search_of_New_Ventures_in_a_Technology_Cluster_The_Role_of_Ties_with_Service_Intermediaries?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ==https://www.researchgate.net/publication/227516623_Innovation_Search_of_New_Ventures_in_a_Technology_Cluster_The_Role_of_Ties_with_Service_Intermediaries?el=1_x_8&enrichId=rgreq-c57ab579-bd28-4d38-a7a6-fd86761b6d39&enrichSource=Y292ZXJQYWdlOzI3NDczNzE3MjtBUzoyMTkxNDg2Mzk1NzYwNjRAMTQyOTI2MDUxNTgzMQ== Empirical Social Research (University of Cologne, Germany). Use of the Eurobarometer studies is relatively common in academic empirical research in the management field (e.g., Kwon and Arenius, 2010; Tether, 2005; Tether and Tajar, 2008a). The database includes responses of 5238 companies from innovation-intensive industry sectors. The sample contains approxi- mately 200 cases from each country surveyed, with the exception of Malta, Cyprus and Luxemburg (70 cases) and non-EU countries (100 cases). Sampling in each country reflected two stratification criteria: company size and sector of activity. Therefore, sampling was con- ducted following the recommendations of the Oslo Manual (OECD/ EUROSTAT, 2005, 121): “Given that the innovation activities of units in different industries and different size classes can differ significantly, it is recommended that the stratification of random sample innovation surveys should be based on the size and principal activity of the units”. Therefore, this type of data selection and collection eliminates the possibility of nonresponse bias, rendering each country in the subsample representative in terms of sector, activity and size. The fieldwork was conducted between October 15th and Octo- ber 23rd, 2007 through telephone interviews conducted by the national institutes associated with EOS Gallup Europe. The person interviewed at each company was a top-level executive responsible for strategic decision making. Descriptive statistics reveal that firms in the sample had an average of 376 employees and that a total of 4361 companies were established before the year 2000 (incumbents), whereas 864 companies were established after that date (new ventures). Moreover, 47.5% of the firms had introduced new or significantly improved products during the previous two years. This ratio was similar for new ventures (47.6%) and incumbents (47.5%). With regard to public support for innovation, 9.8% of the firms had received subsidies for acquiring machinery, equipment or software; 15.5% had received subsidies for buildings or other infrastructure; 8.6% had applied for tax reductions for their R&D expenditures; 19% had received funding for networking with other companies; 13.4% had received funding for networkingwith universities and research institutes; 13.9% had received public support for attending trade fairs; 21.8% had received funding for marketing information; and 12.9% received direct support for financing innovation projects. These percentages are similar for new ventures and incumbents. Finally, descriptive statistics also demonstrated that all these types of public Table 1 Variable description. Variable name Definition Operationalization Dependent variables Firm performance Evolution of the firm's turnover during the previous two years (2005 and 2006). It is represented by six categories: (1) had decreased by over 25%; (2) had decreased by 5–25%; (3) approximately the same; (4) had increased by 6–25%; (5) had increased by 26–50%; (6) had increased by over 50%. Product innovation Introduction of new or significantly improved products during the previous two years. 1 if the company has introduced new or significantly improved products, 0 otherwise. Independent variables Subsidies Economic funding not requiring repayment for innovation activities. It is represented by two proxies: 1 if the company has received subsidies for acquiring machinery, equipment or software, 0 otherwise. 1 if the company has received subsidies for acquiring buildings or other infrastructure, 0 otherwise. Tax incentives Reduction in the amount of taxes that a company must pay on a percentage of its innovation spending. 1 if the company has received tax incentives for innovation activities, 0 otherwise. Networking support Public support to facilitate companies' establishment of formal or informal communication channels for sharing knowledge of and resources for innovation activities. It is represented by two proxies: 1 if the company has received support for networking with other firms, 0 otherwise. 1 if the company has received support for networking with universities and research institutes, 0 otherwise. Marketing information support Public support to provide elaborate, abundant and accurate information on market conditions that will be useful for innovation activities. It is represented by two proxies: 1 if the company has received support for attending or participating in trade fairs or trade missions, 0 otherwise. 1 if the company has received support for acquiring information on market needs, market conditions and new regulations, 0 otherwise. Direct support for financing innovation projects Public activities providing favorable financial conditions, in terms of lower (or a lack of) enforcement mechanisms and interest rates. 1 if the company has received direct support to finance innovation projects, 0 otherwise. Control variables Firm size Number of employees Sector of activity OECD classification (NACE Rev.2, 2 digits level) It is represented by six categories: (1) high technology products; (2) medium–high technology products; (3) medium–low technology products; (4) low technology products; (5) knowledge-intensive services; (6) less knowledge-intensive services. R&D expenditures R&D intensity Thousands of Euros spent yearly on R&D per 100 employees. Regional R&D Regional R&D investment per capita Thousands of Euros per capita spent yearly on R&D in the region (NUTS 2) where the company operates. Regional GDP GDP per capita of region (NUTS 2) where the company operates. Country A dummy variable for the country where the company operates. R. Antolín-López et al. / Technovation ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎ 5 Please cite this article as: Antolín-López, R., et al., Fostering product innovation: Differences between new ventures and established firms. Technovation (2015), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002i http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 instruments were represented in every country considered, with the exception of Norway (where tax reductions and subsidies for buildings and other infrastructures were not represented). Consequently, the data display sufficient variability for testing the relationships among the different public incentive instruments and innovation outcomes for both new ventures and established firms. 3.2. Measures This section describes all the variables and how they were measured (see Table 1). As indicated above, we aimed to analyze the connection of several public support policies and firm product innovation and performance. The hypotheses propose that new ventures and established firms differ regarding that relationship. Consequently, company age was used to divide the sample into two groups as the first step in testing the two proposed models. No general agreement among scholars can be employed to identify what con- stitutes a new venture with respect to innovation activities. Although some authors have considered a narrow and young age to indicate that a firm is a new venture (e.g., Tether, 2005), most innovation studies have considered a broader age range of up to 7–8 years (e.g., Antolin-Lopez et al., 2013; Schoonhoven et al., 1990; Wiklund et al., 2010; Zhang and Li, 2010). Consistent with the latter approach, our study considered a firm as a new venture when it was founded during the previous seven years because new firms require some time before being able to utilize/employ/make use of public support programs and transform their help into successful innovations. In addition, it often takes time for innovationto influence firm performance. 3.2.1. Dependent variables The dependent variable in this study, product innovation, has been measured as the introduction of new or significantly improved products during the previous two years. Previous studies have also used dichotomous variables (if the company has innovated in terms of product) as measures of innovation output (e.g., Martinez-Ros, 2000; Revilla and Fernandez, 2012). 3.2.2. Independent variables We have considered which public instruments should be included among the public innovation policies that are designed or provided specifically for new ventures. Therefore, we have studied the public instruments most frequently included in the innovation policies examined rather than assessing a specific innovation program. In fact, the European Competitiveness Council (2006, 2) noted the following: “Innovation policy should be best understood as a set of instruments”. According to the European Commission (COM, 2009), the most widely used forms of public support over the previous three years were tax incentives, subsidies and grants, funding for networking, and facilitat- ing the acquisition of information regarding market conditions. As discussed above, descriptive statistics confirm the representation of these types of public instruments in a large number of countries. Subsidies consist of economic funding that does not require repayment and these have been represented by two proxies: (1) subsidies for acquiring machinery, equipment or software and (2) subsidies for acquiring buildings or other infrastructure devoted to innovation activities. Tax incentives reduce the amount of taxes that a company must pay on a percentage of its innovation spending (Norrman, 2008). These reductions can typically be carried forward for a certain number of years (usually 15 years) until the company has obtained benefits. This element has been measured using the following dummy variable: “In the last two years, has your company received tax reductions for R&D to support product innovation?” Support for networking refers to the public initiatives designed to facilitate and promote the establishment of formal or informal channels of communication with the purpose of sharing knowledge and resources to develop innovation activities (Schwartz et al., 2012). To render this variable operational, two dichotomous variables were considered: public support for networking with other firms and public support for networking with universities and other research institutions. Marketing information refers to public support activities designed to provide elaborate, abundant and accurate information on market conditions that will be useful for conducting innovation activities. This feature was represented by two dummy proxies: (1) public support for attending or participating in trade fairs or trade missions and (2) public support for acquiring information regarding market needs, market conditions, new regulations, etc. Finally, direct support for financing innovation projects includes public activities that provide favorable financial conditions in terms of lower (or a lack of) enforcement mechanisms and interest rates. This feature was measured by asking firms whether they had received “direct support to finance R&D-based innovation projects”. 3.2.3. Control variables Several control variables have been included to account for alternative explanations. First, a control variable was included for firm size, in accordance with the innovation literature (Radas and Bozic, 2009; Revilla and Fernandez, 2012), because our sample exhibits size variability among new ventures and established com- panies. Previous empirical research shows that the advantages of size for a firm's innovation capabilities are ambiguous. On the one hand, larger firms may possess greater financial resources and be favored by economies of scale and scope, which thereby increases the profitability of their innovation strategies; on the other hand, smaller firms are more flexible and less bureaucratic, which may increase innovation efficiency (Damanpour, 1991). Firm size was measured by the natural logarithm of the number of employees. A control for sector of activity was included following previous studies that suggest that innovative firms' performance depends on the nature of the industry in which they are operating (e.g., Damanpour et al., 1989). Knowledge-intensive or technology- intensive activities may offer different technological opportunities and thus influence the development of product innovation. There- fore, the activity sector was broken down into six categories, in accordance with the OECD classification (NACE Rev.2, 2 digits level): high technology products, medium–high technology products, med- ium–low technology products, low technology products, knowledge- intensive services, and less knowledge-intensive services. R&D expenditures have also been included as a control since R&D intensity is commonly used to assess inputs to the innovation process (Hitt et al., 1996). We have related R&D expenditures to firm size; therefore, R&D expenditures have been measured in thousands of Euros spent annually on R&D per 100 employees. We have standar- dized this variable by taking the ratio of the firm R&D expenditures to the sector (NACE 2 digits) R&D expenditures average. Finally, some controls have been included that address firms' geographical origins because public instruments promoting innovation may vary significantly among European countries and regions in terms of intensity and regulatory conditions. A dummy variable for each country appearing in the database has been calculated to control for differences in economic conditions, business culture and/or interpre- tation of the different concepts investigated in the survey. 3.3. Common-method bias A major concern in survey research is the use of perceptual data for both independent and dependent variables (self-reported data), which can result in common-method bias. Although common- method bias cannot be avoided in this study, we feel confident R. Antolín-López et al. / Technovation ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎6 Please cite this article as: Antolín-López, R., et al., Fostering product innovation: Differences between new ventures and established firms. Technovation (2015), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002i http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 that it presents no serious problems with respect to testing the hypotheses. Because the hypotheses tested in this paper, which were phrased as “some relations are stronger in one subsample than in the other,” are quite different from the European Commis- sion's aims when the survey was designed, the likelihood that respondents were able to determine the hypotheses tested in this paper is extremely low. In addition, respondents could not directly influence hypotheses' acceptance or rejection with their answers – even if they anticipated them – because answers also depend on the responses obtained in another subsample. However, several proce- dures were used during both the questionnaire design and the reporting stages to reduce the potential for common-method variance (OECD/EUROSTAT, 2005; Podsakoff et al., 2003). Moreover, a latent class factor analysis was run using LATENT GOLD 4.5 to estimate the presence of common-method biases in the data. If there were common-method variance in our data, a model consist- ing of a single factor would emerge as the best statistical solution. BIC and CAIC criteria were selected to compare model solutions based on both their model fits and parsimony. The BIC criterion exhibited better performance than other classification criteria (Biernacki and Govaert, 1999), and CAIC is preferred over AIC2 or AIC3 for large samples because it imposes a much larger penalty, which leads to a smaller number of factors (Bozdogan, 1987). Applying the minimumCAIC and BIC values rule, the optimal number of factors in these data varied between two and three, respectively. Thus, both approaches indicated that a model with one factor was not the most appropriate, which suggests that common- method bias is not a serious problem in this study. 3.4. Analysis The main problem when analyzing the relationship between subsidies (or financial aid instruments) and product innovation is the potential endogeneity of the subsidy and the sample selection bias. The allocation of these aids fails to satisfy the randomness property that a social experiment should possess because firms may apply for public funding if they actually innovate, and public agencies may base their subsidizing decisions on the applying firms' capacity to innovate. Thus, product innovation is likely to precede the allocation process, which makes public funding an endogenous variable. In addition, the factors taken into account to apply for a public support program can differ, although some of them may be the equal to those that affect the firm's product innovation. This fact can generate a bias in the impact of these support instruments on firms' product innovation in our sample. This issue has previously been addressed in the literature (e.g., Almus and Czarnitzki, 2003; Busom, 2000; Czarnitzki and Fier, 2002; Czarnitzki and Lopes-Bento, 2011; Huergo and Moreno, 2014; Lach, 2002; Wallsten, 2000), and several methodologies have been proposed to address this problem. For example, Busom (2000) developed a two-stage model in which she initially estimated the probability of participating in a public funding program and, in the second stage, R&D activity was regressed on several covariates, including a selection term that incorporated a firm's tendency to receive public funding. However, this mechanism only allows evaluating the impact of a single funding mechanism. Aiming to reflect the effects of a set of public policies collectively, Almus and Czarnitzki (2003) applied a nonparametric matching approach. In the same line, to account for the differences between European and national funding programs, Czarnitzki and Lopes- Bento (2014) applied a multiple treatment effect model that con- sidered the propensity scores of 12 different change possibilities by comparing the actual situation (m) of: not receiving funding; receiv- ing only national funding; receiving only EU funding or funding from both sources with a counterfactual situation with the same possibi- lities (l). This methodology assumes that a counterfactual situation for companies in the state m can be estimated from the sample of companies receiving l (Czarnitzki et al., 2007). However, the higher the amount of different sources of public funding considered, the more complex the matching matrix becomes. With respect to our case, accounting for eight different types of publicly funded schemes would require handling 56 different cases and it would only consider the possibility of receiving funds from one program at a time. Thus, this methodol- ogy is inapplicable to our data. All the approaches discussed have pros and cons and there are no benchmarks to guide the selection of one methodology or another (Almus and Czarnitzki, 2003). Finally, the econometric model employed is driven by the characteristics of the data analyzed (Heckman et al., 1998). In order to account for treatment effects, in this paper we follow Heckman's (1979) methodology, which has been used for addressing both selection and endogeneity problems (e.g. Huergo and Moreno, 2014). Following this two-step model, we initially estimate a selection equation for the participation in each one of the publicly funded schemes we assess using a multivariate probit model. In the second step, we analyze the effect of this participa- tion on product innovation. Our first set of equations expresses the participation of a given firm i in a publicly funded scheme m (m¼1,2,3,…,8). This multi- variate probit model can be written as follows: yimn¼ β 0 mXimþ ϵim; m¼ 1;…;8 yim ¼ 1 if yimn 40 and 0 otherwise where A im; m¼ 1;…; 8 are error terms distributed as multi- variate normal, each with a mean of zero and a variance– covariance matrix V, where V has values of 1 on the leading diagonal and correlations ρjk ¼ ρkj as off-diagonal elements (Cappellari and Jenkins, 2003). To account for the endogeneity problem, we first use some regional-level and country-level variables as instruments (these variables are not used in the second step) which are determined outside the firm but affect the probability of receiving public support for innovation. Public instruments promoting innovation may vary significantly among European countries and regions in terms of intensity and regulatory conditions. In order to address firm' geogra- phical origins, a dummy variable for each country appearing in the database has been included to control for differences in economic conditions, business culture and/or interpretation of the different concepts investigated in the survey. After an initial test, we only retained the more significant country variables. Moreover, regional GDP per capita and regional R&D investment per capitawere included as an explanatory variable because the region may play an important role in innovation policy in Europe (Radas and Bozic, 2009). Regional GDP and R&D data were obtained from EUROSTAT Statistics. Second, the obtained predictions of the probability of participat- ing in each program are used as endogenous variables in the second step to predict product innovation instead of actual participation (Huergo and Moreno, 2014). Because our dependent variable was measured as a dichotomous variable, we used a probit model to estimate this equation. Country dummies variables not used in step one were used as control variables in this step. This process is repeated both for new ventures and established firms. 4. Results Table 2 provides descriptive statistics and a correlationmatrix for all the variables used in the study. Multicollinearity should not be a concern for this sample because the correlations between the vari- ous items are well below .70, which suggests that the variable has R. Antolín-López et al. / Technovation ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎ 7 Please cite this article as: Antolín-López, R., et al., Fostering product innovation: Differences between new ventures and established firms. Technovation (2015), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002i http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 discriminant validity (Cohen et al., 2003). Moreover, variance inflation factor tests were conducted to verify the absence of multicollinearity. The results were satisfactory, as all values were between 1.0 and 1.6, and tolerance values were largely distant from 0, with the lowest value being .485. Therefore, there is sufficient evidence to rule out multi- collinearity in the data (Hair et al., 1999). To test our hypotheses, two models were estimated separately for each of the two groups, new ventures and incumbent firms. Our econometric model was applied in two steps. The results from the multivariate probit analysis determining the probability of participation in publicly funded schemes are shown in Table 3 for new ventures and Table 4 for established companies. Next, the predictions of the probability of participating in each program were used as the input for the second probit model that assessed the relationship between those programs and product innovation. Table 5 shows the results of this analysis for both new ventures and established companies. Subsidies are not good predictors of the development of product innovation among new ventures. However, they are positively and significantly related to incumbents' product innova- tion in the case of subsidies for the acquisition of buildings or other infrastructure for innovation activities and thus provide somesupport for Hypothesis 2a. Tax reductions were found to be significantly and positively related to product innovation within the incumbent subsample, although they were not significant for new ventures. This finding confirms the argument that tax reductions are more important to fostering the development of product innovation in established companies. Therefore, the results support Hypothesis 2b. With respect to variables relating to publicly funded support for networking, support for networking the one focused on networking with companies is significantly related to innovation only for new ventures. Networking with universities and research institutes seems to be not significantly linked with the development of new or improved products in both the new venture and incumbent subsamples. These results provide some support for Hypothesis 1a. Two items were proposed to measure public support for increas- ing marketing information. The first one, “support for acquiring information on market needs, market conditions and new regula- tions”, exhibited a negative and non-significant relationship for both incumbent companies and new ventures. The second variable, “sup- port for attendance at or participation in trade fairs”, was found to be significant and positively associated with product innovation for new ventures, whereas it remained negative and significant for established firms. These results provide partial support for Hypothesis 1b. In examining direct support for financing R&D-based innova- tion projects we observed that this type of public instrument is not positively related to innovation in any of the samples analyzed; moreover, it is surprisingly negatively linked related with both established firms and new ventures. These findings do not support Hypothesis 1c. Finally, regarding control variables, size is not significant for new venture subsample but it is positive and significant among estab- lished firms. Spending on innovation has a positive and significant coefficient in both subsamples. Considering the sector of activity, we noted some differences between new ventures and established companies in terms of the significance of the coefficients. For example, new ventures operating in medium–high technology sector are less directly associated with the development of new products than those firms in low-technology sectors, which served as the base. 5. Discussion This study combines insights from the competency-based per- spective and innovation policy and entrepreneurship literatures to analyze the effect of public support instruments on product innovation at new ventures and at incumbent firms. We analyze a comprehensive dataset to extend the current literature by (1) posit- ing the notion that innovation policy instruments have different effects on new ventures than on incumbent firms, and by (2) sug- gesting a competency-based logic that explains these varied effects. Consequently, this paper draws from previous studies to take the first step in advancing knowledge regarding which innovation policy instruments are more adequate to foster product innovation in new ventures compared with incumbents. With respect to our first research goal, we found that there is a completely different pattern of relationships among diverse types of innovation policy instruments and product innovation among new ventures and incumbent firms. More specifically, we found that public policies promoting networking with other companies and public policies facilitating support for attending trade fairs and trade missions were more important to product innovation for new ventures, whereas subsidies for acquiring buildings and infrastruc- tures for innovation activities, in addition to tax incentives for R&D expenses, were more relevant to product innovation at incumbent firms. Therefore, an important contribution of this paper is to show that not all innovation policy instruments are equal in how they affect product innovation in new ventures and incumbents. With respect to our second research goal, we suggest that these differences are related to the power of the innovation instruments to provide key competitive capabilities to the firm. Specifically, innova- tion policy instruments that aim at providing capabilities typically lacking in new ventures – those that contribute to the liability of newness –should be particularly effective at promoting innovation at new ventures. In other words, the fit between the resources that a given innovation policy instrument provides and a firm's capabilities and/or weaknesses matters. Our results seem to suggest a logic in designing public support initiatives that incentivize R&D. The results reveal that for established firms, both tax incentives for R&D and subsidies for buildings or other infrastructure for innovation activities that do not require repayment were signifi- cantly related to product innovation. Surprisingly, that was not the case of subsidies for acquiring machinery, equipment or software. Perhaps those types of subsidies might be more useful for the development of other types of innovation, such as processes or organizational innovations. However, altogether those results suggest that public incentives aiming at generating financial capital are especially useful for incumbent firms since they provide funds whose use in innovative projects might be approved even in the face of uncertainty, thus unraveling firm's capacity to experi- ment and develop new products (Damanpour, 1991). Public policies facilitating support for specific innovation project financing seem to be negatively related to product innovation in both cases. This kind of aid requires firms to repay the loan received which may hinder new product development as it increases profit- ability uncertainty. In addition, this negative effect may be attrib- uted to either the loss of focus on new product development at some stage of the process, caused by the lag time between receiving the grant and the end of the new product innovation process or the poor design of these incentives (Radas and Bozic, 2009). Results confirm that for new ventures, public support for coop- eration and networking with other firms is particularly valuable when developing new products. New ventures possess few valuable contacts, which limit their external search scope (Aspelund et al., 2005; Zhang and Li, 2010). In addition, such support offers access to partners' knowledge, technology, human capital and complementary capabilities (Zahra and Filatotchev, 2004) that new ventures may be unable to access in another way due to their resource limitations. We have also found that engagement in product innovation increases if a new venture received support for attending or participating in trade fairs. These findings fit the so-called “open innovation” model R. Antolín-López et al. / Technovation ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎8 Please cite this article as: Antolín-López, R., et al., Fostering product innovation: Differences between new ventures and established firms. Technovation (2015), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002i http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 Table 2 Descriptive statistics and correlation among variables. Variable Mean S.D. Obs. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 1 Product innovation .48 .50 5163 1 2 Performance .70 .98 4476 .048** 1 3 Subsidies for acquiring machinery, equipment or software .16 .36 4232 .06** .016 1 4 Subsidies for buildings or other infrastructure for innovation activities .10 .30 4227 .01 –.02 .42nn 1 5 Tax reductions for R&D expenditures .09 .28 4096 .12** .01 .22** .16** 1 6 Support for networking with companies .19 .39 4259 .09** .03* .20** .17** .17** 1 7 Support for networking with universities and research institutes .13 .34 4264 .11** .02 .20** .19** .25** .47** 1 8 Support for attending or participating in trade fairs or trademissions .24 .43 4240 .13** 0 .23** .20** .19** .45** .39** 1 9 Support for information on market needs, market conditions, new regulations, etc. .22 .41 4236 .06** –.01 .15** .17** 16** .53** .39** .51** 1 10 Direct support for financing innovation projects .13 .34 4219 .11** .03 .29** .22** .34** .24** .33** .21** .19** 1 Control variables 11 R&D expenditures 4159.30 11,402.76 3259 .08** 0 .02 .04* .01 .02 .02 .03 –.02 .06** 1 12 Size 376.11 2290.78 5169 .03* .02 .01 .03 .06** .06** .09** .01 .04* .04* –.04* 1 13 Sector: high technology .03 .17 4616 .07** .02 .03 .01 .04* .03 .03 .05** .02 .06** –.01 –.01 1 14 Sector: medium–high technology .12 .32 4616 .13** .05** .03 –.02 .09** .02 .09** .05** .02 .06** .01 .01 –.06** 1 15 Sector: medium–low technology .15 .36 4616 .06** .02 .03 –.02 .04* .01 –.02 0 –.01 .03* –.03* –.03* –.07** –.15** 1 16 Sector: low technology .16 .36 4616 .10** –.13** .06** .02 0 –.05** –.01 .04* –.02 –.01 –.02 –.02 –.07** –.16** –.18** 1 17 Sector: knowledge-intensive-based services .24 .43 4616 –.16** .08** –.05** .02 –.03 .05** .07** –.05** .01 .02 .04** .04** –.10** –.20** –.24** –.24** 1 18 Sector: less knowledge-intensive-based services .31 .46 4616 –.09** –.03 –.05** –.01 –.08** –.05** –.11** –.04* –0 –.10** 0 0 –.12** –.24** –.28** –.29** –.38** 1 19 Regional GDP 2316 1578 5236 .01 .02 –.06** –.01 .10** .06** .05** 0 .03* .04** .05** .05** –.02 –.03* –.05** –.11** .16** .01 1 20 Regional R&D 1422 1145 5225 .03* .04** -.09** -.03* 0 .04* .04* -.06** -.01 .04** .09** .08** 0 -.01 -.05** -.11** .15** -.01 .516** Country dummies not shown. n Po .05 (2-tailed). nn Po .01 (2-tailed). R . A n to lín -Ló p ez et a l. / Tech n o va tio n ∎ ( ∎ ∎ ∎ ∎ ) ∎ ∎ ∎ – ∎ ∎ ∎ 9 P lease cite th is article as: A n to lín -Ló p ez, R ., et al., Fo sterin g p ro d u ct in n o vatio n : D ifferen ces b etw een n ew ven tu res an d estab lish ed fi rm s. Tech n o vatio n (2 015 ), h ttp ://d x.d o i.o rg/10 .1016 /j.tech n o vatio n .2 015 .0 2 .0 0 2 i http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 (Chesbrough, 2003). Many authors have argued in favor of the benefits of opening the innovation process to external knowledge flows, suggesting that both internal and external ideas are relevant for the development of successful innovations (Chesbrough and Crowther, 2006; Rigby and Zook, 2002), particularly with respect to new ventures that lack market experience. Research that analyzes entrepreneurship from a strategic man- agement perspective should complete its models by considering the Table 3 Participation in publicly funded schemes by new ventures. Multivariate Probit Model. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) Size .013 (.064) .062 (.071) .085 (.075) .022 (.058) .221nnn (.060) .051 (.056) � .030 (.055) .179** (.062) R&D expenditures .000 (.001) .000 (.001) .001 (.001) .000 (.001) .001 (.001) .000 (.001) � .000 (.001) .001** (.000) Sector of activity High technology .497 (.430) .681 (.453) 1.138* (.459) .541 (.438) � .116 (.471) .686 (.437) .430 (.442) .407 (.479) Medium–high technology � .210 (.278) � .710 (.432) � .150 (.337) .341 (.252) � .193 (.275) .036 (.258) .288 (.249) .335 (.310) Medium–low technology � .065 (.263) � .248 (.343) � .344 (.368) .078 (.255) � .094 (.274) � .184 (.254) � .052 (.252) .251 (.306) Low technology Base Base Base Base Base Base Base Base Knowledge-intensive-based services � .377 (.225) � .079 (.257) � .417 (.278) � .087 (.202) � .211 (.218) � .223 (.201) .062 (.193) .125 (.253) Less knowledge-intensive-based services � .441* (.213) � .061 (.245) � .426 (.261) � .242 (.199) � .558* (.224) � .356 (.199) .046 (.187) � .170 (.258) Country dummies Entered Entered Entered Entered Entered Entered Entered Entered Regional GDP (/10,000) .062 (.069) .017 (.083) .226** (.084) .035 (.074) .109 (.076) .025 (.070) � .050 (.073) .106 (.082) Regional R&D � .080 (.084) � .181 (.106) � .112 (.106) .002 (.083) � .169 (.093) � .077 (.081) .038 (.080) � .002 (.091) Constant � .894* (.356) �1.314** (.404) �1.914*** (.441) �1.155** (.335) �1.841*** (.355) � .869** (.324) � .674* (.314) �2.395*** (.401) Number of observations 475 Wald chi (96) 145.36 Prob4chi2 .001 Log likelihood �1164.718 The entries in the table are coefficients, with standard errors in parentheses. All correlation coefficients across equations are significant at .05. (1) Subsidies for acquiring machinery, equipment or software; (2) Subsidies for buildings or other infrastructure for innovation activities; (3) Tax reductions for R&D expenditure; (4) Support for networking with companies; (5) Support for networking with universities and research institutes; (6) Support for attending or participating in trade fairs or trade missions; (7) Support for information on market needs, conditions, new regulations, etc.; (8) Direct support for financing innovation projects. n Po .05 (2-tailed). nn Po .01 (2-tailed). nnn Po .001. Table 4 Participation in publicly funded schemes by established companies. Multivariate Probit Model. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) Size .099nnn(.026) .093*** (.029) .171*** (.029) .116*** (.024) .204*** (.026) .047* (.024) .093*** (.024) .133*** (.027) R&D expenditures .001* (.000) .001 (.000) .000 (.000) .001* (.000) .001* (.000) .001 (.000) .000 (.000) .001** (.000) Sector of activity High technology .004 (.178) � .195 (.242) .021 (.221) .283 (.186) .060 (.201) � .205 (.180) .021 (.190) .426* (.184) Medium–high technology � .079 (.113) � .084 (.141) .435*** (.130) .016 (.120) .207 (.123) � .024 (.109) � .032 (.115) .196 (.125) Medium–low technology � .012 (.100) � .027 (.126) .151 (.124) .164 (.105) � .161 (.121) � .085 (.097) � .030 (.102) .251* (.114) Low technology Base Base Base Base Base Base Base Base Knowledge-intensive-based services � .382*** (.106) � .072 (.123) � .270* (.130) .147 (.103) .099 (.111) � .304** (.098) .024 (.100) � .059 (.116) Less knowledge-intensive-based services � .294** (.095) � .037 (.113) � .296*** (.124) .050 (.098) � .230* (.110) � .169 (.089) .046 (.092) � .252* (.113) Country dummies Entered Entered Entered Entered Entered Entered Entered Entered Regional GDP (/10,000) � .050 (.028) � .018 (.032) .182*** (.028) .059* (.024) .046 (.027) .007 (.024) .061** (.023) .055* (.028) Regional R&D � .077* (.038) � .050 (.043) � .092* (.041) .013 (.031) .016 (.035) � .068* (.032) � .066* (.032) .042 (.035) Constant �1.156*** (.144) �1.677*** (.170) �2.520*** (.182) �1.796*** (.142) �2.342*** (.159) � .824*** (.133) �1.433*** (.137) �2.068*** (.162) Number of observations 2263 Wald chi (112) 569.78 Prob4chi2 .000 Log likelihood �6094.910 The entries in the table are coefficients, with standard errors in parentheses. All correlation coefficients across equations are significant at .05. (1) Subsidies for acquiring machinery, equipment or software; (2) Subsidies for buildings or other infrastructure for innovation activities; (3) Tax reductions for R&D expenditure; (4) Support for networking with companies; (5) Support for networking with universities and research institutes; (6) Support for attending or participating in trade fairs or trade missions; (7) Support for information on market needs, conditions, new regulations, etc.; (8) Direct support for financing innovation projects. n Po .05 (2-tailed). nn Po .01 (2-tailed). nnn Po .001. R. Antolín-López et al. / Technovation ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎10 Please cite this article as: Antolín-López, R., et al., Fostering product innovation: Differences between new ventures and established firms. Technovation (2015), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002i http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 role played by public policies in promoting and developing entre- preneurial firm resources (e.g., knowledge) andcapabilities. New ventures may possess certain important resources but may not have sufficient time to develop the capabilities required to manage them. External support might explain why some entrepreneurial firms build and alter these capabilities more efficiently than others. Entrepreneurship scholars have analyzed particular types of resources to understand differences in firm performance, particu- larly in terms of the ability to identify entrepreneurial opportunities (Ireland et al., 2003). Information, social capital, and entrepreneurial experiences are examples of these resources. The analysis of complementary capabilities, such as product innovation – which is particularly relevant to overcome the “liability of newness” – and emphasis on developing the capabilities required to manage new ventures' specific resources may enrich this line of research. Finally, interest among academics and policy makers in under- standing the efficacy and efficiency of different public incentives that support innovation is growing (e.g., Norrman, 2008; Santamaria et al., 2010). Although such analysis is beyond the scope of this study, our results may provide useful insights into the relationship between the most common public incentives that support innovation and firms' development of new products, by highlighting the differences between the characteristics of new ventures and those of incumbent firms. These differences should be considered in studies analyzing whether and how public support incentives have long-term effects on recipient firms. 5.1. Implications for policy makers We analyzed data gathered from 29 different countries. A comparison of the effects of a number of incentives on product innovation in a variety of economic and institutional frameworks provides policy makers with information about which policies or policy portfolios work best to achieve particular goals. The first practical implication of our study is that public policies should make a distinction between new ventures and established firms. Thus, the final selection of public support instruments will depend on the goals pursued by the policy maker. Innovation support policies are typically assumed to affect new ventures and incumbents equally, but our results indicate that such is not the case. Different instru- ments have different effects on firms depending on their age, resources and capabilities. Policy makers should favor innovative new ventures because it entails positive externalities for society (e.g. Arrow, 1962; Nelson, 1959). Although much remains to be learned about this relationship, our paper sheds some light on how this goal might be achieved. Specifically, policy makers should emphasize programs that support networking with other companies and attending trade fairs and/or trade missions to foster product innovation in new ventures. For incumbents, tax reductions for R&D expenditures, subsidies for acquiring R&D infrastructures and support for obtaining information on market needs and trends are the most effective policies. The conclusions of this paper may help refine the efficiency of innovation policy instruments. For example, a particular instrument might be effective at promoting product innovation among new ventures, but its effect on incumbents' innovation might be negli- gible. In this case, limiting the policy to the target group of firms (i.e., to new ventures) might help save valuable public resources. In addition, this line of research is also valuable to managerial practice because it provides guidance on which public programs are more appropriate for new ventures and/or incumbents. 5.2. Limitations and future research avenues This study has limitations that are caused in part by its exploratory nature and by the characteristics of the database design. The database has been compiled using a large number of companies over a wide variety of industrial sectors, and it covers a considerable Table 5 Relationship between publicly funded schemes and innovation. Probit Models. New ventures Established companies Subsidies for acquiring machinery, equipment or softwarea �16.576 (10.809) 3.849 (2.800) Subsidies for buildings or other infrastructure for innovation activitiesa 32.973 (18.508) 5.545nn (1.768) Tax reductions for R&D expenditurea .991 (4.018) 2.886n (1.361) Support for networking with companiesa 35.153n (16.333) 6.579 (3.559) Support for networking with universities and research institutesa 4.051 (5.263) � .038 (1.937) Support for attending or participating in trade fairs or trade missionsa 21.341nn (7.819) �11.256nnn (3.069) Support for information on market needs, conditions, new regulations, etc. a �14.882 (8.479) �3.225 (2.700) Direct support for financing innovation projectsa �8.234n (3.960) �7.073n (2.974) Controls Sector of activity: High technology �11.820 (6.710) � .196 (.278) Medium–high technology �1.399n (.684) .238 (.163) Medium–low technology .086 (.601) � .399n (.173) Low technology Base Base Knowledge-intensive-based services .086 (.601) �1.406nnn (.233) Less knowledge-intensive-based services 3.833 (2.060) � .846nnn (.171) Size � .343 (.288) .141n (.069) R&D expenditures .215nn (.074) .218nnn (.029) Country dummies Entered Entered Constant �12.886n (5.694) � .130 (.519) Number of observations 502 2390 χ 2 (d.f.) 94.71 (30) 291.600 (28) P-value .000 .000 Log likelihood �290.059 �1465.559 Pseudo R2 .162 .093 The entries in the table are coefficients, with standard errors in parentheses. The reference category is “not to develop new or improved products”. a The predictions of the probability of participating in each programme are obtained from Table 3 for new ventures and Table 4 for established companies, respectively. n Po .05 (2-tailed). nn Po .01 (2-tailed). nnn Po .001. R. Antolín-López et al. / Technovation ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎ 11 Please cite this article as: Antolín-López, R., et al., Fostering product innovation: Differences between new ventures and established firms. Technovation (2015), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002i http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 number of countries and includes a more extensive range of different public innovation support instruments than previous studies. These features guarantee a reasonable basis for generalizing results. Nonetheless, this database has shortcomings: first, our data cover only those firms with 20 employees or more to guarantee a minimum activity and organizational structure. However, there might be new ventures excluded from our study because they have not had the time to achieve this minimum threshold. As a consequence, new ventures in our study are relatively large or fast growing. Conclusions may be carefully generalized or assumed for small or slow-growth new ventures. Second, the database's cross- sectional nature renders testing for causal effects over time impos- sible. Third, this study includes subjective performance measures through the use of direct questions for respondents. Because of the EU's anonymity policy, correlating this information with a second- ary objective dataset is not possible. Although the presence of common-method bias in the dataset cannot be excluded, the nature of the hypotheses, the application of recommendations from Podsakoff et al. (2003) and the statistical tests applied suggest that common-method bias is not a cause for concern in this study. In addition, product innovation has been measured using a dummy variable. However, this element constitutes a complex phenomenon, and measuring innovation with a dichotomous variable may lead to a lack of information on the new product development process. Finally, this paper has analyzed only one type of innovation. Therefore, our conclusions should not be extended to other types and future work might focus on others, such as organizational or process innovation, in order to study possible differencesbetween new ventures and incumbents. The following points can be viewed as possible future avenues of research for the development of this study. It would be informative to assess how different innovation policy instruments work together. For example, it could be the case that specific instruments mutually complement and reinforce each other, while other might not exert this effect or even might counter-balance the effect of one instrument. One long-term goal of future works on this research stream could be to examine the suitability of specific configurations of innovation policy instruments to foster innovation in specific types of firms (i.e. new ventures and incumbents). Other interesting avenue of research would consist in assessing the effect of the innovation policy instruments differentiating between radical and incremental product innovations and adding the frequency of new product introductions and time to market. Acknowledgements The authors acknowledge financial support from the Spanish Ministry of Economy and Competitiveness (National R&D Project ECO2011-24921 and predoctoral grant program), the European Regional Development Fund (ERDF/FEDER), the Ministry of Educa- tion (FPU Program), the University of Almeria’s (UAL, ceiA3) predoctoral grant program, and CySOC. References Aerts, K., Schmidt, T., 2008. Two for the price of one? Additionality effects of R&D subsidies: a comparison between Flanders and Germany. Res. Policy 37 (5), 806–822. Almus, M., Czarnitzki, D., 2003. The effects of public R&D subsidies on firms' innovation activities: the case of eastern Germany. J. Bus. Econ. Stat. 21 (2), 226–236. Alvarez, S., Busenitz, L., 2001. The entrepreneurship of resource based theory. J. Manag. 27 (6), 755–775. Antolin-Lopez, R., Martinez-del-Rio, J., Cespedes-Lorente, J., 2013. Cooperación y competencia como antecedentes de la innovación de producto. ¿Aplican las empresas nuevas y establecidas una lógica diferenciada? Investig. Eur. Dir. Econ. Empresa 19 (1), 53–62. Arrow, K.J., 1962. Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. In: Nelson, R.R. (Ed.), The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity: Economic and Social Factors. Princeton, N.J., pp. 609–625. Arthurs, J.D., Busenitz, L.W., 2006. Dynamic capabilities and venture performance: the effects of venture capitalists. J. Bus. Ventur. 21 (2), 195–215. Aspelund, A., Berg-Utby, T., Skjevdal, R., 2005. Initial resources' influence on new venture survival: a longitudinal study of new technology-based firms. Techno- vation 25 (11), 1337–1347. Baker, T., Nelson, R.E., 2005. Creating something from nothing: resource construc- tion through entrepreneurial bricolage. Adm. Sci. Q. 50 (3), 329–366. Berube, C., Mohnen, P., 2009. Are firms that receive R&D subsidies more innovative? Can. J. Econ. 42 (1), 206–225. Blanes, J.W., Busom, I., 2004. Who participates in R&D subsidy programs? The case of Spanish manufacturing firms. Res. Policy 33 (10), 1459–1476. Biernacki, C., Govaert, C., 1999. Choosing models in model-based clustering and discriminant analysis. J. Stat. Comput. Simul. 64 (1), 49–71. Bosse, D.A., 2009. Bundling governance mechanisms to efficiently organize small firm loans. J. Bus. Ventur. 24 (2), 183–195. Bozdogan, H., 1987. Model selection and Akaikes information criterion (AIC): the general theory and its analytical extensions. Psychometrika 52 (3), 345–415. Bruton, G.D., Ahlstrom, D., Li, H.-L., 2010. Institutional theory and entrepreneurship: where are we now and where do we need to move in the future? Entrep. Theory Pract. 34 (3), 421–440. Bruton, G.D., Rubanik, Y., 2002. Resources of the firm, Russian high-technology startups, and firm growth. J. Bus. Ventur. 17 (6), 553–566. Burg, E., Podoynitsyna, K., Beck, L., Lommelen, T., 2012. Directive deficiencies: how resource constraints direct opportunity identification in SMEs. J. Prod. Innov. Manag. 29 (6), 1–12. Burke, A., Fraser, S., Greene, F.J., 2010. The multiple effects of business planning on new venture performance. J. Manag. Stud. 47 (3), 391–415. Busom, I., 2000. An empirical evaluation of the effects of R&D subsidies. Econ. Innov. New Technol. 9 (2), 111–148. Cappelen, Å., Raknerud, A., Rybalka, M., 2012. The effects of R&D tax credits on patenting and innovations. Res. Policy 41 (2), 334–345. Cappellari, L., Jenkins, S.P., 2003. Multivariate probit regression using simulated maximum likelihood. The Stata Journal 3 (3), 278–294. Chesbrough, H., 2003. Open Innovation: The New Imperative for Creating and Profiting from Technology. Harvard Business School Press, Boston, MA. Chesbrough, H., Crowther, A.K., 2006. Beyond high tech: early adopters of open innovation in other industries. R&D Manag. 36 (3), 229–236. Cohen, J., Cohen, P., West, S.G., 2003. Applied Multiple Regression/Correlation Analysis for the Behavioural Sciences. Erlbaum, Mahwah, NJ. COM, 2009. Making Public Support for Innovation in the EU More Effective: Lessons Learned from a Public Consultation for Action at Community Level. Commission of the European Communities, Brussels. Council of the European Union 2006. Council conclusions on a broad-based innovation strategy: strategic priorities for innovation action at the EU level. In: Proceedings of the 2769th Council Meeting of Competitiveness Council, Brussels. Czarnitzki, D., Ebersberger, B., Fier, A., 2007. The relationship between R&D collaboration, subsidies and R&D performance: empirical evidence from Fin- land and Germany. J. Appl. Econom. 22 (7), 1347–1366. Czarnitzki, D., Fier, A., 2002. Do innovation subsidies crowd out private invest- ment? Evidence from the German service sector. Appl. Econ. Q. 48 (1), 1–25. Czarnitzki, D., Hanel, P., Rosa, J.M., 2011. Evaluating the impact of R&D tax credits on innovation: a microeconometric study on Canadian firms. Res. Policy 40 (2), 217–229. Czarnitzki, D., Lopes-Bento, C., 2014. Innovation subsidies: Does the funding source matter for innovation intensity and performance? Empirical evidence from Germany. Czarnitzki, D., Lopes-Bento, C., 2013. Value for money? New microeconometric evidence on public R&D grants in Flanders. Res. Policy 42 (1), 76–89. Damanpour, F., 1991. Organizational Innovation: a meta-analysis of effects of determinants and moderators. Acad. Manag. J. 34 (3), 555–590. Damanpour, F., Szabat, K.A., Evan, W.M., 1989. The relationship between types of innovation and organizational performance. J. Manag. Stud. 26 (6), 587–601. Danneels, E., 2002. The dynamics of product innovation and firm competences. Strateg. Manag. J. 23 (12), 1095–1121. David, P., Hall, B., Toole, A., 2000. Is public R&D a complement or substitute for private R&D? A review of the econometric evidence. Res. Policy 29 (4), 497–529. Gans, J.S., Stern, S., 2003. The product market and the market for “ideas”: commercialization strategies for technology entrepreneurs. Res. Policy 33 (2), 333–350. Gonzalez, X., Pazo, C., 2008. Do public subsidies stimulate private R&D spending? Res. Policy 37 (3), 371–389. Gilsing, V.A., van Burg, E., Romme, A.G., 2010. Policy principles for the creation and success of corporate and academic spin-offs. Technovation 30 (1), 12–23. Hair, J.F., Anderson, R.E., Tatham, R.L., Black, W.C., 1999. Analisis Multivariante. Prentice Hall, Madrid. Hall, B., van Reenen, J., 2000. How effective are fiscal incentives for R&D? A review of the evidence. Res. Policy 29 (4–5), 449–469. Heckman, J.J., 1979. Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica: J. Econom. Soc. 47 (1), 153–161. Heckman, J.J., Ichimura, H., Smith, J., Tood, P., 1998. Characterizing selection bias using experimental data. Econometrica: J. Econom. Soc. 66 (5), 1017–1098. R. Antolín-López et al. / Technovation ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎12 Please cite this article as: Antolín-López, R., et al., Fostering product innovation: Differences between new ventures and established firms. Technovation (2015), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002i http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref1http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref1 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref1 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref1 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref2 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref2 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref2 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref2 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref3 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref3 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref4 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref4 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref4 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref4 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref5 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref5 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref5 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref6 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref6 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref7 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref7 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref7 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref8 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref8 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref9 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref9 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref9 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref10 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref10 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref10 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref11 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref11 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref12 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref12 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref13 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref13 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref14 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref14 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref14 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref15 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref15 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref16 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref16 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref16 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref17 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref17 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref18 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref18 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref18 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref19 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref19 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref19 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref500 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref500 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref20 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref20 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref21 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref21 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref21 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref22 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref22 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref23 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref23 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref23 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref24 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref24 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref24 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref24 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref24 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref25 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref25 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref26 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref26 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref26 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref26 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref27 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref27 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref27 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref28 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref28 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref29 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref29 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref30 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref30 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref31 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref31 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref31 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref31 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref31 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref32 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref32 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref32 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref33 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref33 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref33 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref34 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref34 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref35 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref35 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref36 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref36 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref36 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref37 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref37 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref38 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref38 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 Hitt, M.A., Hoskisson, R.E., Johnson, R.A., Moesel, D.D., 1996. The market for corporate control and firm innovation. Acad. Manag. J. 39 (5), 1084–1119. Huergo, E., Moreno, L., 2014. National or International Public Funding? Subsidies or Loans? Evaluating the Innovation Impact of R&D Support Programmes. Uni- versity Library of Munich, Germany, No. 54218. Ireland, R.D., Hitt, M.A., Sirmon, D.G., 2003. A model of strategic entrepreneurship: the construct and its dimensions. Strateg. Manag. J. 29 (6), 963–989. Keizer, J.A., Dijkstra, L., Halman, J.I.M., 2002. Explaining innovative efforts of SMEs. An exploratory survey among SMEs in the mechanical and electrical engineer- ing sector in Netherlands. Technovation 22 (1), 1–13. Kleinschmidt, E.J., Cooper, R.G., 1991. The impact of product innovativeness on performance. J. Prod. Innov. Manag. 8 (4), 240–251. Klette, T.J., Møen, J., Griliches, Z., 2000. Do subsidies to commercial R&D reduce market failures? Microeconometric evaluation studies. Res. Policy 29 (4), 471–495. Kwon, S.-W., Arenius, P., 2010. Nations of entrepreneurs: a social capital perspec- tive. J. Bus. Ventur. 25 (3), 315–330. Lach, S., 2002. Do R&D subsidies stimulate or displace private R&D? Evidence from Israel. J. Ind. Econ. 50 (4), 369–390. Lado, A.A., Wilson, M.C., 1994. Human resource systems and sustained competitive advantage: a competency-based perspective. Acad. Manag. Rev. 19 (4), 699–727. Marion, T., Friar, J.H., Simpson, T.W., 2012. New product development practices and early-stage firms: two in-depth case studies. J. Prod. Innov. Manag. 29 (4), 639–654. Martin, S., Scott, J.T., 2000. The nature of innovation market failure and the design of public support for private innovation. Res. Policy 29 (4), 437–448. Martinez-Ros, E., 2000. Explaining the decisions to carry out product and process innovations: the Spanish case. J. High Technol. Manag. Res. 10 (2), 223–242.Nelson, R.R., 1959. The simple economics of basic scientific research. J. Polit. Econ. 67 (3), 297–306. Norrman, C., 2008. Entrepreneurship Policy: Public Support for Technology-Based Ventures. Doctoral dissertation, Linköping University, Linköping. Norrman, C., Klofsten, M., 2009. An entrepreneurship policy programme: implica- tions and expectations. Entrep. Innov. 10 (1), 33–42. Oakey, R.P., 2003. Funding innovation and growth in UK new technology-based firms: some observations on contributions from the public and private sectors. Venture Cap. 5 (2), 161–179. OECD/EUROSTAT, 2005. Oslo Manual: Guidelines for collecting and interpreting innovation data. Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development, and Statistical Office of the European Communities, EUROSTAT, Paris. Ozgen, E., Baron, R.A., 2007. Social sources of information in opportunity recogni- tion: effects of mentors, industry networks, and professional forums. J. Bus. Ventur. 22 (2), 174–192. Peneder, M., 2008. The problem of private under-investment in innovation: a policy mind map. Technovation 28 (4), 518–530. Podsakoff, P.M., MacKenzie, S.B., Lee, L.Y., 2003. Common method biases in behavioral research: a critical review of the literature and recommended remedies. J. Appl. Psychol. 88 (5), 879–903. Prahalad, C.K., Hamel, G., 1990. The core competence of the corporation. Harv. Bus. Rev. 68, 79–91. Radas, S., Bozic, L., 2009. The antecedents of SME innovativeness in an emerging transition economy. Technovation 29 (6–7), 438–450. Revilla, A.J., Fernandez, Z., 2012. The relation between firm size and R&D productivity in different technological regimes. Technovation 32 (11), 609–623. Rigby, D., Zook, C., 2002. Open-market innovation. Harv. Bus. Rev. 80 (10), 80–89. Sakakibara, M., 1997. Heterogeneity of firm capabilities and cooperative research and development: an empirical examination of motives. Strateg. Manag. J. 18 (S1), S143–S164. Sakakibara, M., 2002. Formation of R&D consortia: industry and company effects. Strateg. Manag. J. 23 (11), 1033–1050. Santamaria, L., Barge-Gil, A., Modrego, A., 2010. Public selection and financing of R&D cooperative projects: credit versus subsidy funding. Res. Policy 39 (4), 549–563. Schoonhoven, C.B., Eisenhardt, K.M., Lyman, K., 1990. Speeding products to market: waiting time to first product introduction in new firms. Adm. Sci. Q. 35 (1), 177–207. Schwartz, M., Peglow, F., Fritsch, M., Günther, J., 2012. What drives innovation output from subsidized R&D cooperation? Project-level evidence from Ger- many. Technovation 32 (6), 358–369. Sine, W.D., Lee, B.H., 2009. Tilting at windmills? The environmental movement and the emergence of the US wind energy sector. Adm. Sci. Q. 54 (1), 123–155. Stinchcombe, A.L., 1965. Social structure and organizations. In: March, G. (Ed.), Handbook of Organizations. Rand McNally, New York. Storey, D.J., Tether, B.S., 1998. Public policy measures to support new technology- based firms in the European Union. Res. Policy 26 (9), 1037–1057. Teece, D.J., 1986. Profiting from technological innovation: implications for integra- tion, collaboration, licensing and public policy. Res. Policy 15 (6), 285–305. Tether, B.S., 2002. Who co-operates for innovation, and why: an empirical analysis. Res. Policy 31 (6), 947–967. Tether, B.S., 2005. Do services innovate (differently)? Insights from the European Innobarometer Survey. Ind. Innov. 12 (2), 153–184. Tether, B.S., Tajar, A., 2008a. The organisational-cooperation mode of innovation and its prominence amongst European service firms. Res. Policy 37 (4), 720–739. Tether, B.S., Tajar, A., 2008b. Beyond industry–university links: sourcing knowledge for innovation from consultants, private research organisations and the public science-base. Res. Policy 37 (6–7), 1079–1095. Walsh, S.T., Linton, J.D., 2001. The competence pyramid: a framework for identify- ing and analyzing firm and industry competence. Technol. Anal. Strateg. Manag. 13 (2), 165–177. Wallsten, S., 2000. The effects of government–industry R&D programs on private R&D: the case of the SBIR program. RAND J. Econ. 31 (1), 82–100. Wiklund, J., Baker, T., Shepherd, D., 2010. The age-effect of financial indicators as buffers against the liability of newness. J. Bus. Ventur. 25 (4), 423–437. Woolley, J.L., Rottner, R.M., 2008. Innovation policy and nanotechnology entrepre- neurship. Entrep. Theory Pract. 32 (5), 792–811. Yang, C.-H., Huang, C.-H., Hou, T.C., 2012. Tax incentives and R&D activity: firm level evidence from Taiwan. Res. Policy 41 (9), 1578–1588. Zahra, S.A., Filatotchev, I., 2004. Governance of the entrepreneurial threshold firm: a knowledge-based perspective. J. Manag. Stud. 41 (5), 885–897. Zhang, Y., Li, H., 2010. Innovation search of new ventures in a technology cluster: the role of ties with service intermediaries. Strateg. Manag. J. 31 (1), 88–109. R. Antolín-López et al. / Technovation ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎ 13 Please cite this article as: Antolín-López, R., et al., Fostering product innovation: Differences between new ventures and established firms. Technovation (2015), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002i http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref39 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref39 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref40 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref40 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref40 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref40 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref41 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref41 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref42 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref42 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref42 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref43 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref43 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref44 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref44 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref44 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref44 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref45 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref45 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref46 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref46 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref46 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref46 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref47 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref47 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref47 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref48 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref48 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref48 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref49 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref49 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref50 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref50 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref51 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref51 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref52 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref52 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref53 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref53 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref54 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref54 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref54 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref55 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref55 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref55 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref56 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref56 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref56 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref57 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref57 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref58http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref58 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref58 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref59 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref59 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref60 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref60 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref61 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref61 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref61 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref62 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref63 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref63 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref63 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref64 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref64 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref64 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref65 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref65 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref65 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref65 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref66 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref66 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref66 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref67 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref67 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref67 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref67 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref68 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref68 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref69 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref69 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref70 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref70 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref71 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref71 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref72 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref72 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref73 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref73 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref74 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref74 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref74 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref75 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref75 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref75 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref76 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref76 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref76 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref77 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref77 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref77 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref77 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref78 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref78 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref79 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref79 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref80 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref80 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref80 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref81 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref81 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref82 http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0166-4972(15)00012-7/sbref82 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.02.002