Buscar

[Peter_Flaschel,_Willi_Semmler_(auth.) - Competition, Instability, Nonlinear Cycles

Prévia do material em texto

Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems 
For information about Vols. 1-128, please contact your bookseller or Springer-Verlag 
Vol. 129: H.-J. LUthi, Komplementaritats- und Fixpunktalgorithmen in 
der mathematischen Programmierung. Spieltheorie und Okonomie. 
VII, 145 Seiten. 1976. 
Vol. 130: Multiple Criteria Decision Making, Jouy-en-Josas, France. 
Proceedings 1975. Edited by H. Thiriez and S. Zionts. VI, 409 pages. 
1976. 
Vol. 131: Mathematical Systems Theory. Proceedings 1975. Edited 
by G. Marchesini and S. K. Miller. X, 408 pages. 1976. 
Vol. 132: U. H. Funke, Mathematical Models in Marketing. A Collec-
tion of Abstracts. XX, 514 pages. 1976. 
Vol. 133: Warsaw Fall Seminars in Mathematical Economics 1975. 
Edited by M. W. Los, J. Los, and A Wieczorek. V. 159 pages. 1976. 
Vol. 134: Computing Methods in Applied Sciences and Engineering. 
Proceedings 1975. VIII, 390 pages. 1976. 
Vol. 135: H. Haga, A Disequilibrium - Equilibrium Model With Money 
and Bonds. A Keynesian - Walraslan SyntheSIS. VI, 119 pages. 1976. 
Vol. 136: E. Kofler und G. Menges, Entscheidungen bei unvollstandlger 
Information. XII, 357 Seiten. 1976. 
Vol. 137: R. Wets, Grundlagen Konvexer Optlmlerung. VI, 146 Selten. 
1976. 
Vol. 138: K. Okuguchi, Expectations and Stability In Oligopoly Models. 
VI, 103 pages. 1976. 
Vol. 139: Production Theory and Its Applications. Proceedings. Edited 
by H. Albach and G. Bergendahl. VIII, 193 pages. 1977. 
Vol. 140: W. Eichhorn and J. Voeller, Theory of the Price Index. 
Fisher's Test Approach and Generalizations. VII, 95 pages. 1976. 
Vol. 141: Mathematical Economics and Game Theory. Essays In Honor 
of Oskar Morgenstern. Edited by R. Henn and O. Moeschlln. XIV, 
703 pages. 1977. 
Vol. 142: J. S. Lane, On Optimal Population Paths. V, 123 pages. 1977. 
Vol. 143: B. Naslund, An Analysis of Economic Size Distributions. 
XV, 100 pages. 1977. 
Vol. 144: Convex AnalYSis and Its Applications. Proceedings 1976. 
Edited by A Auslender. VI, 219 pages. 1977. 
Vol. 145: J. RosenmUller, Extreme Games and Their Solutions. IV, 
126 pages. 1977. 
Vol. 146: In Search of Economic Indicators. Edited by W. H. Strigel. 
XVI, 198 pages. 1977. 
Vol. 147: Resource Allocation and Division of Space. Proceedings. 
Edited by T. Fujii and R. Sato. VIII, 184 pages. 1977. 
Vol. 148: C. E. Mandl, Simulationstechnik und Simulationsmodelle 
in den Sozial· und Wirtschaftswissenschaften. IX, 173 Seiten. 1977. 
Vol. 149: Statlonare und schrumpfende Bevolkerungen: Demogra-
phisches Null- und Negativwachstum in Osterrelch. Herausgegeben 
von G. Feichtinger. VI, 262 Seiten. 1977. 
Vol. 150: Bauer et aI., Supercritical Wing Sections III. VI, 179 pages. 
1977. 
Vol. 151: C. A SchneeweiB, Inventory-Production Theory. VI, 116 pages. 
1977. 
Vol. 152: Kirsch et aI., Notwendige Optimalitiitsbedingungen und 
ihre Anwendung. VI, 157 Seiten. 1978. 
Vol. 153: Kombinatorische Entscheidungsprobleme: Methoden und 
Anwendungen. Herausgegeben von T. M. Liebling und M. Rossler. 
VIII, 206 Seiten. 1978. 
Vol. 154: Problems and Instruments of Business Cycle Analysis. 
Proceedings 1977. Edited by W. H. Strigel. VI, 442 pages. 1978. 
Vol. 155: MultipleCriteria Problem Solving. Proceedings 1977. Edited 
by S. Zionts. VIII, 567 pages. 1978. 
Vol. 156: B. Naslund and B. Sellstedt, Neo-Ricardian Theory. With 
Applications to Some Current Economic Problems. VI, 165 pages. 
1978. 
Vol. 157: Optimization and Operations Research. Proceedings 1977. 
Edited by R. Henn, B. Korte, and W. Oettli. VI, 270 pages. 1978. 
Vol. 158: L. J. Cherene, Set Valued Dynamical Systems and Economic 
Flow. VIII, 83 pages. 1978. 
Vol. 159: Some Aspects of the Foundations of General Equilibrium 
Theory: The Posthumous Papers of Peter J. Kalman. Edited by J. Green. 
VI, 167 pages. 1978. 
Vol. 160: Integer Programming and Related Areas. A Classified 
Bibliography. Edited by D. Hausmann. XIV, 314 pages. 1978. 
Vol. 161: M. J. Beckmann, Rank in Organizations. VIII, 164 pages. 1978. 
Vol. 162: Recent Developments in Variable Structure Systems, Eco-
nomics and Biology. Proceedings 1977. Edited by R. R. Mohler and 
A Ruberti. VI, 326 pages. 1978. 
Vol. 163: G. Fandel, Opllmale Entscheidungen in Organisationen. 
VI, 143 Selten. 1979. 
Vol. 164: C. L. Hwang and A S. M. Masud, Multiple Objective De-
cision Making - Methods and Applications. A State-of-the-Art Survey. 
XII, 351 pages. 1979. 
Vol. 165: A Maravall, Identification in Dynamic Shock-Error Models. 
VIII, 158 pages. 1979. 
Vol. 166: R. Cuninghame-Green, Minimax Algebra. XI, 258 pages. 
1979. 
Vol. 167: M. Faber, Introduction to Modern Austrian Capital Theory. 
X, 196 pages. 1979. 
Vol. 168: Convex Analysis and Mathematical Economics. Proceedings 
1978. Edited by J. Krlens. V, 136 pages. 1979. 
Vol. 169: A Rapoport et aI., Coalition Formation by Sophisticated 
Players. VII, 170 pages. 1979. 
Vol. 170: A E. Roth, Axiomatic Models of Bargaining. V, 121 pages. 
1979. 
Vol. 171: G. F. Newell, Approximate Behavior of Tandem Queues. XI, 
410 pages. 1979. 
Vol. 172: K. Neumann and U. Steinhardt, GERT Networks and the 
Time-Oriented Evaluation of Projects. 268 pages. 1979. 
Vol. 173: S. Erlander, Optimal Spatial Interaction and the Gravity 
Model. VII, 107 pages. 1980. 
Vol. 174: Extremal Methods and Systems Analysis. Edited by A V. 
Fiacco and K. O. Kortanek. XI, 545 pages. 1980. 
Vol. 175: S. K. Srinivasan and R. Subramanian, Probabilistic Analysis 
of Redundant Systems. VII, 356 pages. 1980. 
Vol. 176: R. Fiire, Laws of Diminishing Returns. VIII, 97 pages. 1980. 
Vol. 177: Multiple Criteria Decision Making-Theory and Application. 
Proceedings, 1979. Edited by G. Fandel and T. Gal. XVI, 570 pages. 
1980. 
Vol. 178: M. N. Bhattacharyya, Comparison of Box-Jenkins and Bonn 
Monetary Model Prediction Performance. VII, 146 pages. 1980. 
Vol. 179: Recent Results in Stochastic Programming. Proceedings, 
1979. Edited by P. Kall and A Prekopa.IX, 237 pages. 1980. 
Vol. 180: J. F. Brotchie, J. W. Dickey and R. Sharpe, TOPAZ - General 
Planning Technique and its Applications at the Regional, Urban, 
and Facility Planning Levels. VII, 356 pages. 1980. 
Vol. 181: H. D. Sherali and C. M. Shetty, Optimization with Disjunctive 
Constraints. VIII, 156 pages. 1980. 
Vol. 182: J. Wolters, Stochastic Dynamic Properties of Linear Eco-
nometric Models. VIII, 154 pages. 1980. 
Vol. 183: K. Schittkowski, Nonlinear Programming Codes. VIII, 242 
pages. 1980. 
continuation on page 343 
Lectu re Notes 
in Economics and 
Mathematical Systems 
Managing Editors: M. Beckmann and W. Krelle 
275 
Competition, Instability, 
and Nonlinear Cycles 
Proceedings of an International Conference 
New School for Social Research 
New York, USA, March 1985 
Edited by Willi Semmler 
Springer-Verlag 
Berlin Heidelberg New York London Paris Tokyo 
Editorial Board 
H. Albach M. Beckmann (Managing Editor) 
P.Dhrymes G. Fandel J. Green W. Hildenbrand W. Krelle (Managing Editor) 
H. P. Kunzi K. Ritter R. Sato U. Schittko P. Schonfeld R. Selten 
Managing Editors 
Prof. Dr. M. Beckmann 
Brown University 
Providence, RI 02912, USA 
Prof. Dr. W. Krelle 
Institut fUr Gesellschafts- und Wirtschaftswissenschaften 
der UniversiUit Bonn 
Adenauerallee 24-42, 0-5300 Bonn, FRG 
Editor 
Prof. Dr. Willi Semmler 
Economics Department, Graduate Faculty, New School for Social Research 
65 Fifth Avenue, New York, N. Y. 10003, USA 
ISBN 978-3-540-16794-5 ISBN 978-3-642-51699-3 (eBook) 
DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-51699-3
Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data. Competition, instability, and nonlinear cycles. 
(Lecture notes in economics and mathematical systems; 275) 1. Business cycles-Mathematical 
models-Congresses. 2. Competition-Mathematical models-Congresses. 3. Prices-Mathematical 
models-Congresses. 4. Macroeconomics-Mathematical models-Congresses.1.Semmler, Willi. 
II. New School for Social Research (New York, N.Y.) III. Series. 
HB3711.C618 1986338.5'4286-20318 
This work is subject to copyright. All rights are reserved, whether the whole or part of the material 
is concerned, specifically those of translation, reprinting, re-use of illustrations, broadcasting, 
reproduction by photocopying machine or similar means, and storage in data banks. Under 
§ 54 of the German Copyright Law where copies are made for other than private use, a fee is 
payable to "Verwertungsgesellschaft Wort", Munich. 
© Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 1986 
contents 
Introduction 
I. On Modeling the Cross-Dual Dynamics of Competition 
P. Flaschel and 
W. Semmler 
R. Kuroki 
R. Franke 
L. Boggio 
T. Fujimoto and 
U. Krause 
The Dynamic Equalization of Profit Rates 
for Input-Output Models with Fixed capital 
The Equalization of the Rate of Profit 
Reconsidered 
A Cross-Over Gravitation Process in Prices 
and Inventories 
stability of Production Prices in a Model 
of General Interdependence 
Ergodic Price Setting with Technical 
Progress 
II. Microfoundations of Macrodynamics and Limit Cycles 
R.M. Goodwin 
G. Dumenil and 
D. Levy 
W. Semmler 
O.K. Foley 
Swinging along the Autostrada 
Stability and Instability in a Dynamic 
Model of Capitalist Production 
On a Microdynamics of a Nonlinear 
Macrocycle Model 
stabilization policy in a Nonlinear 
Business Cycle Model 
1-124 
1 
35 
51 
83 
115 
1.25-211 
125 
132 
170 
200 
IV 
III. Linear and Nonlinear Macrodynamics 
J. Glombowski and 
M. Krueger 
M. Jarsulic 
P. Flaschel and 
R. Picard 
E. Nell 
Some Extensions of a Classical Growth 
Cycle Model 
Growth Cycles in a Classical-Keynesian 
Model 
Problems concerning the Dynamic Analysis 
of a Keynesian Model with Perfect 
Foresight 
cyclical Growth: The Interdependent 
Dynamics of Industry and Agriculture 
IV. Econometrics of the Dynamics of Proportions and Nonlinear 
Macrodynamics 
M. Juillard 
S.N. Neftci 
The stability of the Reproduction Scheme: 
Theoretical Discussion and Empirical 
Evidence for the United States, 1948-1980 
Testing Non-Linearity in Business Cycles 
212-303 
212 
252 
,269 
289 
304-340 
304 
324 
Introduction 
I. The Topic and the structure of the Proceedings 
The papers in this book are the proceedings of a conference held at 
the Economics Department of the Graduate Faculty of the New School for 
Social Research in March 1985 in New York for which financial support 
was provided by .the West German Consulate. The topic of the conference 
was "Competition, Instability, and Nonlinear Cycles." A number of 
mathematical economists from Italy, West Germany, France, Japan, and 
the u.s. were invited as participants in this meeting. 
The conference was preceded by two other conferences in which 
several of the invited scholars had taken part. One, on "la 
gravitation des prix," took place in Nanterre, France,in March 1984. 
The other was held at the New School for Social Research in April 1984 
on "Price of Production in Joint Production systems." Both conference 
were concerned with classical prices of production systems and their 
revival in the form developed by Sraffa and Pasinetti (1977). 
In these conferences, considerable interest arose in more properly 
modeling the dynamics of prices of production systems in a multi-
sectoral framework by utilizing modern mathematical tools of dynamical 
systems. Such a discussion on the dynamics of the classical process of 
competition and the stability of classical production prices was 
originally initiated by several papers by Nikaido (1977, 1983, 1984) 
and further pursued by several scholars (see Steedman, 1983; Boggio, 
1980; Kuroki, 1983; Dumenil/Levy, 1983; Krause, 1983, 1984; Hosoda, 
1985; Filippini, 1985). 
The main idea of the conference at the New School for Social 
Research was to explore the dynamics of production price systems and 
in this way to further a firmer classically oriented microfoundation 
for macrodynamic systems and nonlinear cycle theories. 
The papers can therefore be divided into four parts. In section I 
the dynamics of classical competitive processes and the stability 
properties of production price systems with alternative assumptions on 
the formation of prices and the determination of outputs is explored. 
Section II elaborates on the microfoundations of macrodynamical 
systems and nonlinear cycle theories. Section III presents some 
classical/Keynesian macrodynamical systems, including some corrections 
of sargent's Keynesian macroeconomic models. In section IV some 
econometric methods are provided to test sectoral instabilities in 
VI 
input-output systems and to test nonlinearities and limit cycle 
properties of macroeconomic models. 
II. Notes on the Papers 
Many papers in the first two section of the proceedinqs can be 
understood as a response to Nikaido's papers on the dynamic 
properties of the competitive process in classical economic theory. 
The paper closest to Nikaido's approach is the one by Kuroki in the 
first section of the book. Most of the papers initiated by Nikaido's 
contributions and contained in the first section of the book are 
concerned with the followinq cross-dual process for a qrowinq economic 
system written in terms of a dynamical system of price and quantity 
chanqes in a sequence of time: 
[r (P,X)l - r(p,x») 
where Xl ,Pl are time rates of chanqe of outputs and prices, dl ,kl are 
reaction coefficients, r(p,x)l the industry's profit rate, r(p,x) the 
averaqe profit rate, D(p,X)l the averaqe or expected demand for 
industry i and S(P,X)l the industry's supply. 
Such a dynamical process, includinq both an excess demand function 
and a chanqe in production levels due to differential profit rates, 
can be found in classical economists such as A. Smith, D. Ricardo, K. 
Marx, but also in L. Walras and A. Marshall (see Flaschel/Semmler in 
this volume where a more elaborate introduction to classical dynamics 
is also qiven). Nikaido's papers -- see Kuroki in this volume --
presented results on such a dynamics between output chanqes and 
chanqes in differential profit rates, demonstratinq that in most cases 
prices of production are not even locally stable where lonq- run 
prices of production are formed throuqh the principle of capital flows 
and an equalization of rates of return on capital. The dual of this 
dynamic process of price formation represents the dynamic formation of 
balanced qrowth proportions. 
In classically oriented models such as those initiated by Nikaido 
and elaborated in subsequent discussions, consumer behavior is kept as 
simple as possible. Emphasis is instead qiven to the analysis of the 
behavior of the firm respondinq to differential profit rates throuqh 
capital flows. There exists, of course, a vast literature workinq 
solely with excess demand functions,in which consumption behavior is 
more specified (see Hahn 1982 for a summary). There are also studies 
in qeneral equilibrium theory where a similar dynamic cross-dual 
~I 
process for a production economy is formalized. This appears in 
particular in the work of Morishima (1960, 1964, 1976, 1977), Mas-
Colell (1974), which refer to Hartman's mathematical work on global 
stability of differential equation system (Hartman, 1982) utilizing 
distance functions as Liapunov functions. Another recent approach to 
this problem can be found in the work of Sonnenschein (1981, 1982). 
Yet in most of t~ese studies such a dynamic cross-dual process is 
found to be stable only under specific assumptions on consumption 
behavior (see also Debreu 1982 and Schafer/Sonnenschein 1982). 
In the modeling of classical dynamics initiated by Nikaido'spapers 
where, in particular, the firms' behavior is more specified than in 
the aforementioned types of studies, two different types of price (and 
output) formation are considered. 
In the first type of analysis, a cross-dual dynamics of price and 
output formation is considered with reference to the cross-dual 
process. Here profit rate.differentials determine output changes due 
to the flow of capital, and subsequent imbalances in supply and demand 
(or inventory changes) determine price changes in a multi-sectoral 
system. The stability properties of such dynamic processes are 
discussed in Flaschel/Semmler, Boggio, Franke, Kuroki, Dumenil/ Levy, 
and Goodwin.Different stabilizing forces are considered in the papers. 
Whereas, for example,in the paper by Flaschel/Semmler the rate of 
change of extra profits is utilized as an additional stabilizer for 
the production price system, the papers by Franke and Dumenil/Levy 
model price reactions in response to inventory imbalances and refer to 
consumption behavior and/or firms' control of outputs as additional 
stabilizing force. 
A second type of dynamical process is also considered in the 
sections I and II of this volume. Morishima (1977) calls it a dual 
adjustment process, more popular in Keynesian dynamics.This dynamics 
consists of two adjustment procedures which are, however, considered 
to operate independently of each other. In such theories, prices are 
determined by markups on full cost and prices are decreased 
(increased) when computed prices (cost of production plus a normal 
markup,) exceed (fall short of) actual prices. On the other hand, it 
is then normally assumed that quantities respond to quantity 
imbalances solely or that supply is adjusted to demand 
instantaneously, so that imbalances in supply and demand do not affect 
the formation of long-run prices of production (see Krause/Fujimoto). 
Other versions of these theories have attempted to build into the 
Viii 
dynamic formation of markups also a response to excess demand in 
markets (see the paper of Boggio in this regard). By referring to the 
second type of adjustment process, the paper by Krause/Fujimoto 
obtains global stability results even allowing a choice of technique 
during the price adjustment process by utilizing a theorem on strong 
ergodicity in nonlinear eigenvalue systems. Unlike other papers, they 
also specify the speed of convergence. As Krause has demonstrated in 
other papers, this approach to the dynamics of production prices can 
also be extended to other types of markup pricing behavior (Krause, 
1984). On the other hand, Boggio's paper, which works with given 
techniques and obtains local stability under specified conditions, is 
of great interest for a theory of a price-setting firm facing entry 
and exit barriers. As Boggio also seems to indicate the two types of 
adjustment processes --the cross-dual and the dual adjustment 
processes-- are not necessarily exclusive. The dual process can be 
considered to represent a fast dynamics whereas the cross-dual process 
can be interpreted as representing a slow dynamics. 
In section two of the proceedings, the two types of dynamical 
processes are utilized in several papers as micro-foundations of 
macro- models and limit cycle models. Goodwin's paper explores the 
price and quantity dynamics of a sraffa/von Neumann production price 
system from the point of view of a 2n dimensional potential function 
such as V(q,p,)= pq-paq whose gradients can be used to obtain quite 
elegantly results on the cross-dual dynamical process outlined above 
or on markup price dynamics and quantity dynamics separately. Self-
sustained macroeconomic cycles between unemployment and income shares 
are derived in a multi-sectoral and an aggregated framework based on a 
nonlinear differential equation system of the Lotka/Volterra type. 
The macromodel of Dumenil/Levy is built on a cross-over dynamics 
between differential profit rates causing output changes and 
deviations of actual from normal inventories creating price changes. 
They also take into account quantity constraints and rationing as well 
output control by firms if supply exceeds demand. In spite of the 
local stability of the equilibrium for production prices and the 
balanced growth path, the complexity of their model, which is mainly 
tested by means of computer simulations, unfolds a rich macroeconomic 
dynamics including business cycles and depressions. In Semmler a 
nonlinear macromodel in the tradition of Goodwin (1982), Kalecki 
(1971) and Kaldor (1940) is presented which is built on a classically 
oriented cross-dual microdynamics generating stable limit cycles 
around a qrowth trend for the macromodel. The macromodel is 
demonstrated to be robust aqainst small perturbations and random 
shocks oriqinatinq in the micromodel. 
Foley's paper, on the other hand, explicitly takes into account 
external financinq of the firm and other financial variables. Its 
microdynamics results from price-settinq firms and endoqenously 
qenerated constra~nts for financial funds. A macroeconomic model is 
obtained throuqh aqqreqation of individual firms' behavior, and the 
existence of a limit cycle with qrowth and explicit formalization of 
the monetary flows is proved to exist for certain ranqes of the 
parameters. As also shown, the paper allows one to draw interestinq 
implications for the efficacy of macroeconomic stabilization policy. 
Part III of the proceedinqs is devoted to pure macroeconomic 
dynamics of a qrowinq system, oriqinatinq in the classical/ Marxian 
and Keynesian traditions. In Glombowski/Krueqer, a cycle model with 
qrowth is discussed which includes, in addition to oriqinal Goodwin-
like models, technical chanqe and a formalization of macroeconomic 
imbalances between supply and demand indicated by a utilization of 
capacity variable. Since the model is written in a discrete version, 
it unfolds a rich macroeconomic dynamics for the three nonlinearly 
interactinq variables. Jarsulic also enriches Goodwin's model of 
fluctuatinq qrowth by introducinq a plausible investment function and 
variable utilization of capacity. The existence of a limit cycle is 
proved by use of the Poincare-Bendixson theorem, and more complex 
cases are, as in Glombowski/Krueger, studied by means of computer 
simulations. The work of Flaschel/Picard is devoted to an analysis of 
Keynesian dynamical models starting with a discussion of sargent's 
interpretation of Keynesian dynamics (sargent 1979). By showing some 
defects in Sarqent's dynamic models on Keynesian macroeconomics as 
well as in the economic assumptions underlyinq the models, some 
reformulations of Keynesian dynamics based on a different price 
dynamics than sargent's model are provided. The last paper in this 
section, the paper by Nell, gives a more historical account of a well-
known inter-sectoral dynamics: the interdependent dynamics of industry 
and aqriculture. It utilizes a Nikaido-like model of capital flows 
where the capital flows follow differential profitability in order to 
explain the interdependency of cyclical qrowth in industry and 
aqriculture. 
The section IV of the proceedinqs is concerned with the econometrics 
of the stability of multi-sectoral systems and of nonlinearities in 
x 
macromodels. Juillard tests empirically the stability in proportions 
by making use of comparable input-output tables of the U.S. economy 
for the period of 1948 to 1980. Here empirical evidence is provided 
for the trends as well as the stability of departmental proportions on 
the U.S. post-war economy. Last but not least, Neftci's paper 
elaborates possible ways to test for nonlinearities in aggregated 
macro-data and thus paves the road for testing empirically nonlinear 
cycle models. 
III. Notes on the Mathematical Methods 
The majority of papers inthis volume apply advanced methods of 
differential equations and nonlinear dynamic systems to study the 
microdynamics of competitive processes or the macroeconomic dynamics. 
Among the methods utilized are the gradient method, Liapunov 
functions, the Poincare-Bendixson theorem for limit cycles, discrete 
versions of nonlinear dynamical systems with fixed-point iterations, 
bifurcation theory, and nonlinear eigenvalue theory (ergodicity 
theorems). Since the dynamics of higher order systems is very often 
difficult to elaborate qualitatively with conventional methods, 
several studies in this volume also utilize computer simulations to 
study the dynamic properties of their proposed models. The 
mathematical methods used in these papers have recently been 
elaborated in several books on dynamical systems. The interested 
reader may be referred to more extensive presentations and treatments 
concerning time-continuous as well as discrete versions of dynamical 
systems in Hirsch/smale 1974, Hartman 1982, Ioos/Joseph 1980, 
Guckenheimer/Holmes 1983, and Marsden/Mccracken 1976. 
W.Semmler 
References 
L. Boggio, Full Cost pricing and Sraffa Prices: Equilibrium and 
Stability in a System with Fixed capital, Economic Notes, no. 
1, 1980. 
G. Debreu, Existence of Competitive Equilibrium, in: K.J. Arrow/M.D. 
Intriligator (eds.), Handbook of Mathematical Economics, vol. 
II, (Amsterdam/New York: North Holland) 1982. 
G. Dumenil and D. Levy, The Dynamics of Competition: A Restoration of 
the Classical Analysis (CEPREMAP, Paris) 1983. 
L. Filippini, Concurrenza e Aggiustamento Nei Modelli Lineari di 
Produzioni (Milano: D.A.Giuffre Editore) 1985. 
R.M. Goodwin,Essays in Economic Dynamics (London: McMillan) 1982 
J. Guckenheimer and P. Holmes, Nonlinear Oscillations, Dynamical 
systems and Bifurcations of Vector Fields (Berlin/New York: 
Springer Verlag) 1983. 
F. Hahn, Stability, in: K.J. Arrow/M.D. Intriligator (eds.), Handbook 
of Mathematical Economics, vol. II, (Amsterdam/New York: 
North- Holland) 1982. 
P. Hartman, Ordinary Differential Equations, 2nd ed. (Boston: 
Birkhauser) 1982. 
M.W. Hirsch and S. Smale, Differential Equations, Dynamical systems 
and Linear Algebra (New York: Academic Press) 1974. 
E. Hosoda, On the Classical Convergence Theorem, Metroeconomica, no. 
2, 1985. 
G. Ioos and D.O. Joseph, Elementary stability and Bifurcation Theory 
(Berlin/New York: springer Verlag) 1980. 
N. Kaldor, A Model of Trade Cycle, Economic Journal, 50, 1940. 
M. Kalecki, Selected Essays in the Dynamics of capitalist Economy 
(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press) 1971. 
L.R. Klein and R.S. Preston, Stochastic Nonlinear Models, 
Econometrica, 37, 1969. 
U. Krause, Perron's Theorem without Additivity and Homogeneity, 
University of Bremen, mimeo, 1983. 
U. Krause, Minimal Cost pricing Leads to Prices of Production, paper 
prepared for the conference "La gravitation des prix", 
Nanterre, March, 1984. 
R. Kuroki, The Equalization of Profit Rates Reconsidered, Osaka 
Industrial University, 1983, (in this volume). 
XII 
J.E. Marsden and M. McCracken, The Hopf Bifurcation and its 
Applications (Berlin/New York: Sprinqer Verlaq) 1976. 
A. Mas-Colell, Alqunas Observaciones sobre la Teoria del Tatonnement 
de Walras en Economias Productivas, Anales de Economia, 21, 
1974. 
M. Morishima, A Reconsideration of the Walras-Leontief Model of 
General Equilibrium in: K.J. Arrow/L. Hurwicz (eds.), 
Mathematical Methods in social Sciences (Stanford: Stanford 
University Press) 1960. 
M. Morishima, Equilibrium, Stability and Growth, A Multisectoral 
Analysis (Oxford: Oxford University Press) 1964. 
M. Morishima, The Economic Theory of Modern society (Cambridqe: 
Cambridqe University Press) 1976. 
M. Morishima, Walras' Economics (Cambridqe: Cambridqe University 
Press) 1977. 
H. Nikaido, Refutation of the Dynamic Equalization of Profit Rates in 
Marx's Scheme of Reproduction, Dept. of Economics, University 
of Southern California, no. 7722, 1977. 
H. Nikaido, Dynamics of Growth and Capital Mobility in Marx's Scheme 
of Reproduction, mimeo, 1984. 
H. Nikaido, Marx on Competition, zeitschrift fuer Nationaloekonomie, 
43 (4), 1983. 
L. Pasinetti, Lectures in the Theory of Production (New York, 
Columbia University Press) 1977. 
W. Semmler, Competition, Monopoly and Differential Profit Rates (New 
York, Columbia University Press) 1984. 
W. Shafer and H. Sonnenschein, Market Demand and Excess Demand 
Functions, in: K.J. Arrow/M.D. Intriliqator (eds.), Handbook 
of Mathematical Economics, vol. II (Amsterdam/New York: North-
Holland) 1982. 
H. Sonnenschein, Price Dynamics and the Disappearance of Short Run 
Profits: An Example, Journal of Mathematical Economics, 8, 
1981. 
H. sonnenschein, Price Dynamics Based on the Adjustment of the Firms, 
American Economic Review, vol. 72, no. 5, 1982. 
I. Steedman, Natural Prices, Differential Profit Rates and the 
Classical Competitive Process, The Manchester School, June, 
1984. 
Introduction1 
THE DYNAMIC EQUALIZATION OF PROFIT RATES FOR 
INPUT-OUTPUT MODELS WITH FIXED CAPITAL 
Peter Flaschel' and Willi Semmler·' 
'Department of Economics 
University of Bielefeld 
Universitaetsstrasse, 4800 Bielefeld, FRG 
"Department of Economics, Graduate Faculty 
New School for Social Research 
65 Fifth Avenue, New York, N.Y. 10003 
Recently there have been numerous new interpretations of the 
classical competitive process (Hollander, 1973; Garegnani, 1983; 
Roncaglia, 1978; Shaikh, 1980; Semmler, 1984). There have also been 
several attempts to model classical competitive dynamics. within the 
latter group two trends are emerging. One line of thought explores the 
dynamics of the competitive process on the basis of classical theory 
by referring to supply and demand analysis (Nikaido, 1977, 1983; 
Flaschel, 1983; Flaschel/Semmler, 1985a, 1985b; Dumenil/Levy, 1983, 
1984; Franke, 1985; Boggio, 1984; Steedman, 1984). The other direction 
utilizes the theory of markup pricing to elaborate on the stability 
properties of classically oriented production price systems 
(Nikaido/Kobayashi, 1978; Krause, 1983; Fujimoto/Krause, 1985; Boggio, 
1985; catz/Laganier, 1984). 
In this paper we want to address problems of classical dynamics 
which are related to the supply and demand mechanism. The description 
of the classical dynamics of competition (Steedman, 1984) as well as 
the modeling of it are still of a somewhat elementary and 
heterogeneous nature, especially with regard to the basic dynamics 
involved. Currently there are diverse results presented, ranging from 
the demonstration of instability of the classical competitive process 
(Nikaido, 1977) to the demonstration that it is locally (or even) 
globally stable. Neoclassical economists on the other hand have 
expressed considerable doubts concerning the stability of their 
lWe want to acknowledge, with thanks, helpful discussions and 
comments on an earlier version of the paper by R. Franke, A. Shaikh, 
G. Dumenil, D. Levy, D. Foley, B. Schefold, J. Eatwell, E. Nell and V. 
Caspari. For computational assistance we want to thank R. Zambrano and 
P. Cooney. 
2 
Walrasian short-run models (Hahn, 1970, 1982). Moreover, for long-run 
models of efficient growth and accumulation it has been demonstrated 
in this context that an asymptotically stable adjustment process to 
the steady state can rarely be maintained, once the world of 
homogeneous capital is abandoned (Hahn, 1966, 1970; Kurz, 1968; 
Burmeister et al., 1973). 
since the discussion on classical competitive dynamics is still in 
an early state, a fully acceptable formalization of the process of 
competition including growth cannot yet be expected. Most 
formalizations of classical micro dynamics utilize only a circulating 
capital model, with or withoutcapitalist consumption. The model 
proposed in this paper which is related to other works of the authors 
(Flaschel/Semmler, 1985b, 1986) will include circulating as well as 
fixed capital, but for reasons of simplicity it works with the von 
Neumann assumptions on savings behavior and laborers' consumption. The 
inclusion of fixed capital makes our model comparable with earlier 
work on the dual instability of closed Leontief systems (Jorgenson, 
1960; Zaghini, 1971; Aoki, 1977) where usually two uncoupled dynamical 
systems with fixed capital are discussed, one for output proportions 
and the other for relative prices. 
We will show in section III that our proposed formalization of 
classical competition formulates a cross-dual dynamical process in a 
more plausible and general way than originally proposed for input-
output systems by Nikaido (1977, 1983). In particular, it presents 
results of a more than local nature based on the uniqueness of the 
equilibrium. Our proposed cross-dual dynamics is formalized in section 
III and reconsidered by means of computer simulations in section IV. 
It relies on the interaction of capital movements resulting from flows 
of investments from areas of low to high rates of return, and on the 
other hand, on output changes and their effects on market prices. We 
are able to show that supply changes initiated by differential profit 
rates and related capital flows bring about market price changes and 
thus changes again in differential profit rates. This basic dynamic 
process will produce stable fluctuations around the steady state of 
input-output models with single production and fixed capital. 
Furthermore, it will be demonstrated in section III and IV that this 
cross-dual dynamics will be globally asymptotically stable if the 
direction of the rate of change of differential profit rates is also 
taken into account when capital flows from areas of low to high rates 
of return. Before presenting this dynamical model a brief review of 
3 
classical as well neoclassical literature on competition will be 
given. 
I. Classical Competitive Processes 
I. 1. On Classical Theory 
The verbal analysis of stability in classical economics is 
necessarily ambiguous compared with modern treatments of stability 
problems which utilize formal tools such as dynamical systems, 
Liapunov functions or the global Newton method (Hahn, 1982: Smale, 
1981). On the other hand any interpretation of the classics using 
mathematical tools runs the risk of not accurately depicting the 
classical analysis. Therefore, we wish to present some details of the 
classical competitive process before discussing its possible 
formalizations. 
Of course there exist differences among the classics concerning 
their theory of competition, their concept of long-run prices and the 
role of supply and demand. Yet, they have in common the fact that 
long-run prices (natural prices in Smith and Ricardo, prices of 
production in Marx) are considered to be centers of gravitation which 
are determined independently of short-run demand forces. In smith the 
natural price is composed of the vertically integrated natural wage, 
profit, and rent components. In Marx the prices of production are 
determined by i) the structure of production, ii) the income 
distribution and iii) the turnover time of capital. Long-run changes 
in demand may change the long-run price because of an increasing 
difficulty or facility to produce, possibly requiring new techniques 
of production. However, for the analysis of the stability of the 
market process, demand is given as the average demand (Marx) or 
effectual demand (Smith) and the center of gravitation for market 
prices is considered fixed. The verbally expressed view in the 
classics that market prices fluctuate around or gravitate to long-run 
natural prices indeed relies on the fundamental assumption that the 
cross-dual dynamics between market-price dependent differential profit 
rates and profit-rate dependent output changes is somewhat stable. 
The fundamental classical notion of a crossover dynamics by which 
deviations of profit rates from the average profit rate entail output 
changes and the deviation of supply and demand from long-run average 
demand will cause market prices to move may be expressed in the 
following way: 
4 
<-- (r1 (p,x) - r), i = 1. •• n 
<-- (01 - S1 (p,x», i = 1. •• n 
where P1 and x1 are the time rate of price and quantity changes, D1 is 
the average demand for the industry i, S1 (p,x) the industry i's 
supply, r is the average profit rate for the entire economy and 
r 1 (p,x) is the industry i's profit rate. Thereby the following dynamic 
process is formulated: profit rates above (below) the average lead to 
an increase (decrease) in supply, and an increase (decrease) in supply 
above (below) the average demand in turn will entail a fall (rise) in 
market prices. This dynamic process forces the prices and quantities 
back within certain boudaries. 
Smith referred explicitly to such a twofold process: 
"If at any time it (supply) exceeds effectual demand, some of 
the component parts of its price must be paid below their natural 
rate •.• if it is wages or profit, the interest of labourers in 
the one case, and of their employers in the other will prompt 
them to withdraw a part of their labour or stock from the 
employment ••• If on the contrary, the quantity brought to the 
market should at any time fall short of the effectual demand, 
some of the component parts of its price must rise above their 
natural rate ••• if it is wages or profit, the interest of all 
other labourers and dealers will soon prompt them to employ more 
labour and stock in preparing and bringing it to the market." 
(Smith, 1974, p. 160) 
The supply responds to gains or losses in profits relative to the 
normal, and supply and demand discrepancies entail market price 
changes. The latter adjustment follows from the following process 
described by smith: 
"It is only the average produce of the one species of 
industries which can be suited in any respect to the effectual 
demand; and as its actual produce is frequently much greater and 
frequently much less than its average produce, the quantities of 
commodities brought to the market will sometimes exceed a good 
deal and sometimes fall short a good deal, of effectual demand. 
Even though that demand therefore should continue always the 
5 
same, their market price will be liable to great fluctuations, 
will sometimes fall a good deal below, and sometimes rise a good 
deal above their natural price." 
(smith, 1974, p. 161) 
Such a cross-dual adjustment process for prices and quantities 
initiated by differentials in profit rates and imbalances between 
supply and demand is also formulated by Ricardo (Ricardo, 1951, ch. 
IV). There is not much difference in smith's formulation of this 
gravitational process and Ricardo's as the reader of Chapter IV in 
Ricardo's "principles" will realize. Yet, Ricardo explicitly refers to 
this twofold process by arguing that this process will be brought 
about by competition among owners of capital. In his view the outcome 
does not necessarily require actual capital flows but simply the 
contraction or expansion of industries due to the flows of credit. 
Although neither Smith nor Ricardo has given a proof that this cross-
dual adjustment process is stable, they argue that market prices 
oscillate around their centers of gravitation2 • 
Whereas smith and Ricardo seem to assume that the natural price is 
fixed and given during the adjustment process (steedman, 1984), Marx 
explicitly asks how the prices of production and the equalized profit 
rate are brought about (1977, vol. III, p. 179). Marx also refers to 
the aforementioned twofold process to give a plausible argument for 
equalization of profitrates in the long-run and prices of production 
are established: "The movement of capitals is primarily caused by the 
level of market-prices which lift the profits above the general 
average in one place and depress them below it in another" (Marx, 
1977, vol. III, p. 208). And, 
"Through this incessant outflow and influx, or briefly, through 
its distribution among various spheres, which depends on how the 
rate of profit falls here and rises there, it creates such a 
ratio of supply and demand that the average profit in the various 
spheres of production becomes the same ••• " 
(Marx, 1977, vol. III, p. 195) 
2As one can see in smith's writings on astronomy, he got the notion 
of "gravitation" from Newtonian physics (see smith, 1980). We owe the 
knowledge of this relation between Smith's notion of gravitation and 
Newton's laws of the planetary movements to R. Hei1broner. 
6 
Through this twofold adjustment process, by which capital flows are 
intitiated by profit rates above or below the average and since 
"supply and demand determine the market price" (Marx, 1977, vol. III, 
p. 208) there will be, as Marx assumes, a tendency toward the 
equalization of profit rates and toward prices of production as 
centers of gravitation for market prices. Marx, however, more than 
smith and Ricardo, also stresses that market prices constantly 
oscillate around production prices and supply and demand may fluctuate 
around their equilibrium positions (Marx, 1977, vol III, p. 190). 
Marx, however, was realistic enough not to claim that his 
considerations on the equalization of the general rate of profit 
through competition would necessarily imply the existence of the 
latter in any real economy: 
"This movement of capitals is primarily caused by the level of 
market prices ... Yet, with respect to each sphere of production 
- industry, agriculture, mining, etc. - the transfer of capital 
from one sphere to another offers considerable difficulties, 
particularly on account of the existing fixed capital. 
Experience shows, moreover, that if a branch of industry, such 
as say, the cotton industry yields unusually high profits at one 
period, it makes very little profit, or even suffers losses, at 
another, so that in a certain cycle of years the average profit 
is much the same as in other branches." 
(Marx, 1977, vol. III, p. 208) 
smith and Ricardo as well as Marx never explored sufficiently the 
stability properties of the crossover dynamics which they described. 
Since the verbal formulation of the competitive dynamics in the 
classics is ambiguous, the terms gravitation or oscillation can be 
interpreted in various ways in mathematical terms by means of a 
variety of stability concepts. Some possiblities of a stable behavior 
of this process will be considered in the following. 
I. 2. On Recent Studies of Classical Dynamics 
Already at the turn of the century, the dynamics of equalizing 
profit rates was discussed very controversially in the debate between 
Bohm-Bawerk and Hilferding (see Sweezy, 1949). More recently, Nikaido 
(Nikaido, 1977, 1983) presented formal studies of a different type to 
disprove the Marxian hypothesis of the formation of a general rate of 
7 
profit and the stability of prices of production. By referring to a 
two sector input-output model with simple reproduction, he considers 
in particular the following dynamic system: 
X = A (x + x) + [CO] (1) 
(1' ) 
and either 
Xi = 0 i (r 1 - r 2 ) (2) 
or 
Pi/Pi= 8i (Oi (r1 - r 2 ) - X1 ), i = 1,2 (2' ) 
where A denotes the input-output matrix (augmented by the 
consumption good matrix for labor) and 01 (r1 - r 2 ) the investment 
function for industry i which is dependent on sectoral profit rates 
r 1 , r 2 (01 '>0'02 '<0). If there are no profit rate differentials, then 
0i (0)=0. In (2) supply and demand are instantaneously equated at 
prices which imply the profit rate differential r 1 -r2 • In (2'), due to 
0<8<~, there is a lagged adjustment for prices because of an imbalance 
between intended and realized investments 01 and x1 • Thus equation (2) 
presupposes that the intended level of investment is equal to the 
realized level, whereas (2') allows for lagged adjustment in relative 
prices. This early version of Nikaido's refutation of the equalization 
of profit rates shows strong results (Nikaido, 1977). In the case of a 
higher organic composition of capital in the capital good producing 
sector,the eigenvalues of the dynamic system (1') are both positive 
and the system is totally unstable. For an organic composition in the 
capital good sector which is lower than that of the consumption good 
sector, we obtain eigenvalues ~1<0'~2>0. The equilibrium is thus a 
saddle point. These strong negative results are to some extent 
weakened in his more recent publication (Nikaido, 1983), where he 
differentiates between the flows of money capital and real capital. 
Moreover, capitalist consumption is endogenously determined in this 
revised model. In the case of a higher organic composition of capital 
in the capital goods sector, prices of production remain unstable. The 
case of higher organic composition in the consumption goods sector 
brings a potential for convergence of prices of production in the 
simplest case where money capital moves alone (Nikaido, 1983, p. 339). 
However, Nikaido's formalization of the dynamics of competition is 
not convincing. As is evident, in the light of the characterization of 
8 
classical competition, his formalization does not satisfy the typical 
requirement of a cross-dual dynamics as formulated in 1.1. In both of 
Nikaido's versions of the classical and Marxian theory of competition, 
only one side is formulated correctly; i.e., prices respond to 
quantity imbalances due to (2) and (2'), but the change of the 
relative levels of output Xl' X2 is not really made dependent on 
differentials in profitability in investments. The instability of 
prices of ptoduction in his model comes from the fact that the 
quantity dynamics is unstable by itself3. 
Another paper written in the same vein as Nikaido yields similar 
results (Franke, 1984). Franke removes some inconsistencies in 
Nikaido's approach and discusses the stability in a n-sector model. 
However, due to a modeling of classical and Marxian dynamics similar 
to Nikaido's, Franke also gets negative results for his n-sector 
model. A general proof of instability of prices of production, is not 
provided in his formalization; the instability conclusion is drawn 
from some computer simulations. Boggio has presented another study 
(Boggio, 1984) utilizing excess demand functions and making quantity 
changes dependent on differential profit rates which determine by 
means of a further equation system the differential growth rates. 
Here, asymptotic stability is obtained only for particular types of 
capitalist consumption and specific reaction coefficients of a 
simplified dynamical two sector circulating capital model. In general 
the dynamical process is proved to be unstable. 
The studies by Oumenil/Levy (1983, 1984), which formalize a 
crossover dynamics as it is suggested in 1.1., are capable of 
demonstrating asymptotic stability of prices of production for cases 
where substitution possibilities exist, the reaction of investments to 
differentials in profit rates and the reaction of prices to quantity 
imbalances are not "too large" and where capitalists consume and save. 
The double adjustment mechanism, by which prices change due to 
quantity imbalances and investments respond to differentials in profit 
rates, works as follows in their basic model: 
°i • t - 1 - Y i • t - 1 ] 
Yi • t-l 
(3) 
3In our view a related situation is described by the so-called dual 
(in)stability theorem of closed Leontief models with fixed 
coefficients (see Jorgenson,1960; Zaghini, 1971; Aoki, 1977). 
9 
f(r j • t _ 1 ) (4) 
i = 1,2, j = 1,2, 
1\ 1\ 
where Pi.t-1' Yj .t-1' are the growth rates of prices and quantities. 
The excess demand is determined by: 
(5) 
Pt - 1 d 
with Dt - 1 , Yt - 1 demand and supply of period t-l, ~t-1 the sum of 
profits, a the proportion of profits consumed, d a constant 
consumption good vector for the capitalists which is independent of t. 
Furthermore 
yj. t = Yj. t -1 (1 + gj. t -1) = J't Yj. t -1 f(rj. t -1) 
with gj .t-1 the growth rates of output, which are determined by the 
differential profit rate dependent investments. The scalar J't is an 
index which adjusts the capital fund used up thereby to the available 
capital fund Kt generated by the past period's capital fund Kt - 1 and 
the profit in period t-1. Thus: 
L Yj t_1 f (rj t-1)Pi t-1 a i" i • j' • • J 
(6) 
(In a more recent version, the case of underutilization of the 
available capital fund is also allowed for, and thus Say's Law is 
dispensed with; see Dumenil/Levy, 1984, p. 20). The results of their 
basic model are as follows. With reaction parameters for quantity and 
price changes within a certain range, production prices formulated for 
a two sector model are locally stable and generate balanced growth as 
dual of the equalization of profit rates. But their basic model is 
unstable for simple reproduction and for the von Neumann growth path 
(Dumenil/Levy, 1983). As one would expect, the system becomes more 
flexible if a degree of substitution in demand is allowed for or if 
the quantity of overproduced outputs is taken into account by firms. 
For the two extreme cases a=O and a=l, the system becomes stable after 
allowing for this additional degree of flexibility as is shown by 
means of computer simulations (Dumenil/Levy, 1984) 
The formalization of the dynamics of competition of the classics is 
more satisfactory in this model than in other models. Dumenil and Levy 
capture the crossover dynamics of classical competition sufficiently. 
Some remarks about the character of their model are necessary, 
10 
however. The complexity of the possible results of their model depends 
on the formalization that they have chosen. First, the budget 
constraint for capitalist consumption and the capital fund constraint 
for growth (6) create complicated feedback effects on prices and 
quantities. Thus the question might be raised whether or not these 
constraints produce unnecessary complications not necessarily of great 
importance in a classical model of competition (since sufficient money 
capital or commercial credit might always be available for capital 
flows as, for example, Ricardo assumed). Second, their results are 
also strongly determined by the existence of capitalist consumption 
(a>O). This holds at least for their early version (Dumenil/Levy 
1983) • 
In their early version the dynamical model becomes stable for a>O. 
For a=O there is no convergence unless additional flexibility is built 
in (see Dumenil/Levy 1983, 1984). As known in the literature, 
consumption and sUbstitution in consumption can be introduced in a 
dynamical model as stabilizer (Morishima, 1977, ch.2). Since the 
quality of the behavior of their model changes with this additional 
complexity introduced into their model, it is somewhat left open what 
the true stabilizing forces are in their interpretation of the 
classical competitive process. 
II. Neoclassical Theory of the Competitive Process 
In the history of economic analysis it was not only the classics 
that conceived the aforementioned dual adjustment process. One can 
also find in Walras and Marshall a twofold process which was supposed 
to stabilize capitalist market economies. A closer look at the main 
works of Walras and Marshall shows that the widespread belief that 
Walras conceived of a price and Marshall a quantity adjustment process 
in their stability analysis does not seem to be convincing. A 
classical approach to competition can be found in Walras, for example, 
when he considers the process of groping in a production economy. He 
writes, for example: 
" .•• entrepreneurs use tickets ('bons') to represent the 
successive quantities of products which are first determined at 
random and then increased or decreased according as there is an 
excess selling price over cost of production and vice versa, 
until selling price and cost are equal." (Walras, 1977, p. 242) 
and 
11 
"In fact, under free competition, if the selling price of a 
product exceeds the cost of productive services for certain firms 
and a profit results, entrepreneurs will flow towards this branch 
of production or expand their output, so that the quantity of the 
product (on the market) will increase, its price will fall, and 
the difference between price and cost will be reduced; and if (on 
the contrary), the cost of productive services exceeds the 
selling price for certain firms, so that a loss results, 
entrepreneurs will leave this branch of production or curtail 
their output, so that the quantity of the product (on the market) 
will decrease, its price will rise and the difference between 
price and cost will again be reduced." (Walras, 1977, p. 225) 
If one interprets the notion "cost of production" in the classical 
sense, i.e., profit is included in the cost of production, the 
crossover dynamics the classics conceived is very well formulated in 
this passage by Walras. Moreover, if one adds more explicitly, as 
Walras does, that prices themselves are in general determined by the 
IIlaw of supply and demandll when he describes the process of IIgropingll 
in a pure exchange economy one sees the similarity to the classics 
clearly. With regard to price changes Walras contends that: 
IIGenerally, however, the total demand will not equal total 
offer, of each and every commodity •••• What will happen on the 
market then? If the demand for any commodity is greater than the 
offer, the price of the numeraire will rise; if the offer is 
greater than the demand, the price will fall. 1I 
(Walras, 1977, p. 169) 
Even in Marshall's partial equilibrium analysis, the abovementioned 
twofold adjustment process is considered as central for the 
stabilization of markets. with regard to quantity changes due to 
differential profit rates, Marshall writes: 
IIWhen therefore the amount produced (in a unit of time) is such 
that the demand price is greater than the supply price, then 
sellers receive more than is sufficient to make it worth their 
while to bring the goods to market to that amount; and there is 
at work an active force tending to increase the amount brought to 
12 
sale. On the other hand, when the amount produced is such that 
demand price is less than the supply price, sellers receive less 
than is sufficient to make it worth their while to bring goods to 
market on that scale .•. and there is an active force at work 
tending to diminish the amount brought forward for sale." 
(Marshall, 1947, p. 345) 
On the other hand, concerning price changes due to imbalances of 
supply and demand, we can read: "Market values are governed by the 
relation of demand to stocks actually in the markets" (Marshall, 1947, 
p. 372; see also p. 345 and Marshall's notion of short-run 
equilibrium). Although Marshall develops more carefully the influence 
of long-run changes of demand on the long-run supply price when 
nonconstant returns to scale prevail, his formulation of the dual 
adjustment process is not radically different from the formulation 
that we find in the classics and Walras. In neoclassical analysis of 
adjustments to equilibrium Walras' process of groping and tatonnement 
in an exchange economy mostly only has survived. Morishima's work 
(Morishima,1977) seems to be an exception. 
utilizing, however, excess demand functions and the tatonnementprocess for the demonstration of stability in an exchange economy, 
captures only one side of classical -- as well as Walrasian --
dynamics. This may be one of the reasons why the one-sided short-run 
Walrasian price tatonnement or the so called "Law of Supply and 
Demand" does not produce satisfying stability results in general 
(Hahn, 1982). We conjecture that important stabilizing forces derive 
from side of production and the behavior of the firm which therefore 
must be integrated to give the "law of demand" a solid foundation. 
To investigate this claim, we shall go to the opposite extreme in the 
following section, namely to a model where we focus on production and 
its profitability and where demand is treated in a very preliminary 
fashion. (A further evaluation of the neoclassical literature is given 
in Flaschel/Semmler 1985b). 
13 
III. Capital Movements and Output Reactions in an Input-output system 
with Fixed capital 
In the following a dynamical system is presented based on a n x n 
input-output system with fixed capital. Neither the case of multiple 
techniques nor joint production will be considered here. (The latter 
models are treated in Flaschel/Semmler, 1985b, 1986, where also 
further details with regard to the following brief treatment of our 
adjustment process towards prices of production and steady growth can 
be found). The dynamical system presented here has a unique 
equilibrium, and it allows us to demonstrate global stability results. 
Fixed capital is treated not as a joint product but on the input side, 
as proposed by Brody (1970), Pasinetti (1973) or in conventional 
dynamical versions of input-output models (Woods, 1978, p. 182ff). 
Consider the following equilibrium price and quantity equations: 
AX + g* Bx 
pA + r*pB 
x 
p 
x ?; 0 
p ?; 0 
(1) 
with A the nxn matrix of capital consumed and B the nxn matrix of 
capital advanced (see Brody, 1970 for details). We assume for 
simplicity that A is irreducible and productive and that all columns 
Bj of B and rows Bi of Bare semipositive (?;O). These properties of 
the stock matrix B are a consequence of the property that flow matrix 
A is irreducible if at least a small part of the capital which is used 
up by a process must also be tied up in this process (aij > 0 => bij > 
0; see again Brody (1970) for details]. 
We denote by I the identity matrix, by a prime (') the transposition 
of matrices and vectors and by <x> the diagonal matrix derived from 
a given vector x. 
It is well known (see Woods (1978) for example] that there exists a 
unique equilibrium solution x*, p* (up to scalars a 1 , a 2 ), r*, g* of 
(1) for activities x and prices p such that 
x* >0, p* >0, r* =g* 
(since the two matrices (I-A)-lB, B(I-A)-l are strictly positive and 
have the same dominant eigenvalue A = r*-l, g*-l > 0]. 
We want to investigate the stability of this equilibrium x*, p* with 
regard to a cross-dual adjustment process as discussed in section 1. 
For this purpose, we stipulate the following price and supply 
reactions for this model of fixed capital: 
14 
x • <X>-l X = <d1 >(I - A - rOB) 'p 
p • <p>-l p =-<dz>(I - A - r*B)x (2) 
where x and p denote the time derivative of the vectors x and p [which 
are transformed into vectors for growth rate of activity levels and 
prices by means of the inverses of the diagonal matrices <x>, <p> 
belonging to the vectors x, pl. For the vectors of adjustment speed 
coefficients d 1 , dZ it is assumed that they are elements of the 
positive orthant R! of Rn (d1 , dZ > 0). 
The first part of system (2) states that the growth rate of activity 
j is of the same sign as the term 
PJ - p'AJ - r*p'BJ , 
i.e., the extra profit of sector j per unit of output with regard to 
the steady state rate r* as norm (XJ is therefore proportional to the 
sum of extra profits of sector j]. The second part of (2) on the other 
hand, asserts that market prices Pi react positively (negatively) if 
the current supply Xi falls short of (exceeds) expected demand which 
is here defined by AiX + r*Bix, i.e., current input requirements plus 
the extension of capital advanced r*Bix which is needed for future 
growth (of the norm rate r*). 
As our following stability proofs will show, the dynamics (2) need 
only be considered on certain compact subsets of R!D, which are 
invariant with regard to the stipulated dynamics, i.e., no trajectory 
which starts in such a set can leave it later on. There is 
consequently no need for nonnegativity (positivity) constraints to 
keep the dynamics (2) economically (mathematically) well-defined. The 
proofs of the following propositions will be kept brief, since they 
are similar to those of the joint product system considered in 
Flaschel/Semmler (1985b, 1986). 
proposition 1: The point of rest x*, p* of system (2) is stable in 
the sense of Liapunov, i.e., for every neighborhood U of z* = (x*, 
p*)' E R!D there is a neighborhood U1 of z* in U such that every 
solution z(t) with z(O) in U1 is defined and in U for all t>o. 
Proof: Making use of the new notation z = (x, p)' E R!D we can 
represent the system of differential equations (2) in the compact form 
(3) 
where Q is given by 
[ 
0 
Q -
-(I-A-r* B) 
15 
Note that the matrix Q is skew-symmetric which implies z'Qz = 0 for 
all z E R2n. 
To show stability, we will construct a so-called Liapunov function 
around the given equilibrium z*, i.e. here, a differentiable function 
V on R!D with the strict local minimum z* which fulfils 
V = grad V(z(t»Z(t) ~ 0 (4) 
[see Hirsch/smale (1974, ch. 9) for details]. 
We propose as Liapunov function the function V 
given by 
R!D --> R which is 
V(z) = q'[(z-<z*>ln z) - (z*-<z*>ln z*)] (5) 
where q E R!D is defined by qk dk 1 and (In Z)i by ln Zi' 
It can be easily shown that the equilibrium z* of (2) is a strict 
local minimum of the function V and that grad V(z)' = q' (I-<z>-l<z*». 
For the derivative V of V along the trajectories of (2) we thereby 
get 
V = q' (I-<Z>-l<Z*»Z 
= q'(I-<Z>-l<Z*»<z><d>Qz 
(z - z*) 'Qz 
o 
since <q><d> = I, z* 'Q = 0 and z'Qz=O by the skew-symmetry of Q. 
q.e.d. 
The above proof shows that the function V is constant along the 
orbits of the dynamical system (2). These orbits therefore remain in 
the 'level surfaces' of the graph of V which enclose the minimum 
z*=(x*, P*)' of V. Note that this need not imply that the orbits 
of (2) must be closed. 
The Liapunov function proposed above is well known from Volterra's 
analysis of the n-species case of interacting populations (see Rouche 
et al., 1977, p. 263). In an appropriately extended form this function 
also allows for the treatment of the case of multiple activities and 
the von Neumann inequality approach to joint production and process 
extinction [if free goods are excluded from consideration, see 
Flaschel/Semmler (1985b, 1986)]. 
To obtain asymptotic stability as well, we will now consider the 
following modification of the original dynamics (2). Assume that the 
activity levels not only change with the prevalence of extra profits 
(or losses) but that this change is also dependent on whether these 
extra profits are themselves currently rising or falling. The growth 
16 
rates of activity levels (x) consequently are considered to be 
influenced also by the distribution of signs within the vector 
d • 
s = --(I-A-r"B) 'p = (I-A-r"B) 'p 
dt 
(6) 
This vector shows the direction of change of extra profits or 
losses. 
By means of (6) we suggest a revision of the dynamics (2) of the 
following type (x,p € R~): 
A (7) 
P 
where ~>O is an adjustment parameter. We expect the influence of the 
time rate of change of extra profits to act as an extra stabilizing 
force. 
Inserting the second equation of (7) into (6) gives 
s = (I-A-r"B) '(-<p><d2>(I-A-r"B)x) 
-(I-A-r"B) '<p><d2 >(I-A-r"B)x 
S(p)x 
(8) 
It can be easily shown that the matrix S(p) is negative 
semidefinite, [X'S(p)x~O for all x€R n and that in particular 
x· 'S(p)x"=O]. 
Propostion 2: The system (7) is quasi-globally stable, i.e., each 
sequence of points on a trajectory of (7) in R!n converges to a point 
of rest of (7) [see Hahn (1982, p. 751) for the details of this 
stability concept]. 
We note that the points of rest of the dynamical system (7) must all 
be proportional to the given equilibrium z"=(x" ,p")', since p=O 
implies x=x· and s=O, i.e., x=O implies p=p •. Therefore this 
proposition entails that all trajectories of (7) in R!n approach the 
ray in R!n which is determined by the equilibrium z·=(x" ,p.) '. 
Proof: According to Hahn (1982, p. 751), a process is quasi-globally 
stable if there exists a Liapunov function V for which we can show 
that (i) V- 1 ((-00, c]), c>O is an invariant set with regard to the 
trajectories of (7), (ii) V- 1 ((-00, c]) is compact, i.e., all sequences 
along the trajectories in this set must contain convergent 
subsequences, and (iii) all limit points (of the above convergent 
subsequences) are points of rest. 
From the definition (5) of our former Liapunov function V, it is 
obvious that this function fulfils the second of the above three 
17 
conditions. We shall show in the following that this function (5) also 
fulfills (i) and (iii), demonstrating that our original Liapunov 
function is a Liapunov function in Hahn's senE;e,Le., it implies quasi-
global stability for the revised dynamics (7). 
Ad (i): The new dynamics (7) can be written in compact form as 
" z ... <d>Q (-y ) z (9) 
where Q(~) is given by 
[ ~S(p) 
- (I-A-r* B) 
[see (3) with regard to the other symbols]. 
utilizing the Liapunov function (5) we find for (9), cf. the proof 
of proposition 1: 
V - ql(I - <Z>-l<Z*»Z 
... (z - z*) I Q (-y) z 
... ZlQ(-y)Z 
... ~XlS (p)x :s 0 
since z* IQ(-y)=O, Q(-y)=Q(O)+ y [S~p) :], ZlQ(O)Z 
negative semidefinite. 
0, and since S(p) is 
The above inequality implies that the sets v- 1 «-~, c]), c>o must 
all be (positively) invariant, since V cannot increase along the 
trajectories of (7). 
Ad (iii): Following Hahn (1982, p. 750), we must show that V is 
convergent along the trajectories Z of (7) and constant if and only if 
such a trajectory describes a point of rest. The first of these 
conditions has already been shown [since V is monotonically decreasing 
along all solution curves Z of (7) in R!D and bounded from below]. To 
show the second condition, let us assume that Voz is constant for an 
entire orbit z(t)=(x(t), pet»~ I, ~o in R!D. The condition V = 0 then 
implies xlS(p)x = 0 for this orbit which because of V- 1 «-~,c]) c R!D 
implies (I-A-r*B)x=O. This gives x=Q1x* for some positive scalar Q1 
[which can be shown to be independent of the time parameter t]. 
Inserting this result into (7) gives p=o. i.e., 
x - <d1>(I-A-r*B) Ip ... const. 
Multiplying this equation from the left by w1 ... x* I<d1>-1 gives w12 
... o. Since, however, a constant growth rate xj>O is incompatible with 
our result that the compact sets v- 1 «-~,c]) are invariant, we get Xj 
18 
. . 
= 0 for all j. Hence x - 0, i.e. z z 0, i.e., the assumed orbit z(t) 
is a point of rest. 
q.e.d. 
Remarks: 
1) The above result of quasi-global stability can also be expected 
to hold in the case where the average rate of profit 
p' (I-A)x 
r(x,p) 
p'Bx 
is used instead of the natural rate r*, if a sufficiently large 
parameter ~ is chosen [at least for an appropriately chosen region 
around the equilibrium ray z*]. This assertion has been tested by 
means of computer simulations [see section IV], and it may follow from 
the fact that the discrepancy between the rates r(x,p) and r* may be 
kept small relative to the stabilizing adjustment parameter ~ > o. 
[This possibility of extending our result has been communicated to us 
by R. Franke]. Due to limitations in space, this modification of 
proposition 2 will not be examined in the present paper but is left 
for future investigations. 
2) Brody (1970, p. 90) proposes the following iterative procedure 
for the so-called transformation problem [from values to prices of 
production] : 
P't (I - A)X 
P't+l = pitA + ------
P't Bx 
In the light of our adjustment process (2) this one-sided rule can 
be extended in the following way: 
pit (I - A)Xt 
P't+l = pitA + ------- P't B 
P'tBxt 
P't A + r(xt , Pt) P't B 
P't (I - A)Xt 
------ BXt 
P'tBXt 
= AXt + r(xt , Pt )Bxt 
In time continuous form these adjustment processes can be written as: 
. 
x = - [I - A - r(x,p)B]x 
. p - - [I - A - r(x,p)B]'p 
19 
setting r = r* the following compact form can be utilized: 
with 
G 
and C = (I - A - rOB). 
. 
z Gz 
Neglecting the role of the adjustment coefficients d 1 , d Z our 
proposed adjustment processes can be written as (see system (2)) 
· x <x>(I - A - r* B) 'p 
· p -<p>(I - A - r* B)x 
or in compact form: 
· z = <z>Qz 
with 
Q = [ -: :' ] 
Comparing the matrices G and Q, one realizes that the adjustment 
processes derived from Brody -- and in a more generalized form 
presented in Morishima (1977) as Keynesian adjustment processes -- are 
dual adjustment processes only. Here solely the diagonal of G 
determines the stability property of the adjustment processes. (The 
stability property of these dual adjustment processes can further be 
analyzed by referring to the so-called Metzler matrix, Hahn, 1982, p. 
752). Our proposed adjustment processes, however, represent a cross-
dual dynamics. In its basic formulation (2) with ~ = 0 the off-
diagonal of Q determines the stability property of the system. 
It has been suggested by Morishima that a comparison of these two 
adjustment processes may be of importance in the further analysis of 
the transformation problem. Note, however, that Marx's transformation 
procedure derives from a purely formal redistribution of profits 
between sectors [also in the above reiterated form], whereas our 
proposed adjustment process takes the stylized facts of capitalist 
competition into account, i.e., pays attention to profit rate 
differentials when moving capital between sectors and utilizes a 
simple version of the law of demand as the reference for price 
modifications. An iteration procedure for our proposed dynamics is 
developed in section IV. 
3) The gradient of the average rate of profit r(x,p) = p'(I-A)x/p'Bx 
reads for p and x respectively: 
gradpr(x,p) 
gradx r(x,p) = 
20 
(I-A)x plBx - Bx pi (I-A)x 
(pIBx)2 
(I-A) Ip p'BX - B'p pi (I-A)X 
(pIBx)2 
We denote by u the vector BX/p'Bx and by v the vector B'p/p'Bx. 
Furthermore, let gi denote the current growth rate in the production 
of commodity i and rj sector jls current rate of profit. By means of 
these expressions the above gradient can be reformulated as 
grad r(x,p) = { <v> [ r 1 -:r(x,p) ], <u> [ gl -:r(x,p) ] } 
rn - r(x,p) gn - r(x,p) 
i.e., it measures the discrepancies of sectoral growth and 
profitability with regard to the average rate r(x,p) • 
The dynamical system 
A A (x,p) = - (- gradx r(x,p), gradp r(x,p)) 
therefore is of a similar type as the cross-dual dynamics which we 
have formulated in (2). Furthermore, this kind of dynamics is well-
known in the study of saddle points in non-linear programming [see 
Arrow et al. (1958)]. 
We conjecture therefore that the study of the gradient of the 
average rate of profit may contribute in important ways to an analysis 
of the dynamics of classical competition [cf. also the remark of von 
Neumann (1945/46) concerning the function r(x,p)]. 
4) We have seen in the proof of proposition 2 that w1ln x must be 
constant for a suitably chosen vector w1 • Similarly, w2 lnp will be 
constant for the vector p. l<d2>-1. This implies a particular rule of 
normalization of activity levels x and prices p [which is different, 
but not inferior to the customary one: LXj = 1, LPi = 1]. 
IV. Computer Simulations of the Models 
In the following section, iteration procedures will be developed and 
computer simulations will be presented in order to demonstrate the 
oscillatory character of system (2) and the asymptotic stability of 
system (7). Moreover, in addition to the model presented in section 
III a model with multiple techniques will be considered and simulation 
results given which have not yet been proved mathematically. 
21 
IV.l. A Model with 'Circulating Capital' 
For the purpose of simulations we will here refer to a Leontief 
input-output system and a turnover time of fixed capital equal to one 
(A=B). In the light of Brody's considerations of fixed capital (Brody, 
1970, ch. 1.2), we then get A+r*B=(l+r*)A=R*A. Computer simulations 
are performed for R=l+r~R* and R*=l+r* • 
IV.l.l. Oscillation in the Price-Quantity Dynamics - Modell 
In the first step, we will deal with the dynamic system of single 
production without the additional stabilizing term. For the purpose of 
a computer simulation the system (2) of section III has to be 
rewritten as discrete model. By referring to time derivatives (x,p) 
and setting B = A, the system can be written as: 
. 
(10) 
p 
Assuming <d1 >, <d2 > to be constant, we can derive the following 
system of difference equations which provides us with an iterative 
procedure to approach the question of stability of the equilibrium 
(x* ,po ,R*) : 
(11) 
In addition to our formal proofs, we shall also consider the case 
wherel R* is replaced by the average rate R. utilizing the iteration 
(11), two types of simulation were performed. In the first version the 
rate R changes in each step, since it is calculated as the average 
rate of profit. 
PtAxt 
In the second version of the iteration (11), the ratio R was kept 
constant (and equal to R* in general). For both of these versions as 
well as for model 2 of asymptotic stability to be discussed in the 
next section, the following input-output system, which includes real 
wage goods in the elements of the matrix, was used: 
[
.4 
A-
.3 
.6 ] 
.5 
22 
The maximum eigenvalue of the input-output matrix A is A=.8722, i.e. 
R*=1/A=1.1399. The associated right and left hand eigenvectors with 
the normalization~x~ = 1, ~p~ = 1 are as follows: x; =.7826, x: 
=.6225, p;=.5322, p:=.8466. The ratio of x; to x: is 1.257 and the 
ratio of p; to P: is .62. 
As mentioned, for our first version we assumed R(Xt'Pt) = 1 + r t to 
change in each iterative step. The start vector for outputs was x~ 
=:9, x~ =.6 and their ratio is 1.8. The start vector for prices was P~ 
=.6 and P~ =.6, i.e., p~/p~=1. As can be observed, the start vectors 
are not very close to the vectors associated with the maximum 
eigenvalue. We used the following diagonal matrices as adjustment 
coefficients: 
[.1 0] 
o .2 
d2 = [.2 0] 
o .3 
The results of the iterations with 200 steps are graphically 
demonstrated for R(xt 'Pt) in figures 1, 2, and 3. 
,~.--------------------------------. 
,..1 
,.21 
,.2 
1.1. -,.....:1,--+--\---/--1---1'----+--+--\--+--\--+1 
1.'" 
0 .... 
w ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ = 
T ... 
oscillation of profit 
rates 
Figure 1 
~2~-------------------------------rn 
u, 
'.0 
"" .j-j...----f-----\-----+-----\-----+---I 
Q4 
Q2 
~ ~ ~ ~ ~ = ~ ~ ~ = 
T"'" 
oscillation of relative 
prices 
Figure 2 
The computer simulations for our model with R(xt,pt) revealed what 
has already been conjectured in sections II and III, an oscillatory 
behavior of prices and quantities. In contrast to our mathematical 
demonstration, we now observe an oscillatory movement with slightly 
increasing amplitude in the course of time. The fluctuations of 
relative outputs and prices increase with the number of steps 
performed. Moreover, it was also observable that whenever relative 
23 
Oscillation of relative outputs 
Figure 3 
outputs or prices were close to their respective eigenvectors, the 
duals showed the greatest distance from their respective eigenvectors. 
In addition, with the increasing amplitude of these ratios the average 
profit rate -- and thus the average growth rate -- was also 
fluctuating with an increasing amplitude. The procedure was also 
repeated for different adjustment coefficients and, as would be 
expected, the increase of the adjustment coefficients made the 
fluctuation stronger. 
In general, we obtain the results that the actual price vector is 
mapped into quantity imbalances and the quantity imbalances are mapped 
into price changes. This process continues without any convergence. 
Instead a kind of gravitation (with increasing amplitude) was the 
general outcome. 
In a second version of our model, R was taken as constant and equal 
to R* = 1.1399, the natural rate of profit. By using the same data as 
in the first version and also applying the same start vector to the 
iteration (11), we obtained quite similar results to that of the first 
version of our model. Prices and quantities were continuously 
oscillating (with a slightly increasing amplitude). 
Although according to the reasoning given in section III of the 
paper, we would have expected some kind of regular oscillation for the 
vectors x and p, the actual iteration with the formula (11) showed a 
slightly perturbed behavior in this respect (an increasing 
fluctuation). These slightly different results should be due to the 
24 
difference in the stability properties in the formulation of the 
process in continuous time (10) and in discrete time (11). 
An additional run was performed with an arbitrary R = 1.18. This 
assumes that capital movements are oriented towards a profit and 
growth rate of 18% and not towards the steady profit and growth rate 
of 13.99% or an average profit rate r(xt,pt). The results of the run 
did not differ significantly from the version tested earlier, with the 
provision that the amplitude of the oscillations was increasing 
faster. 
This allows us to conclude that the orientation of capital flows 
toward any arbitrary average profit rate in the neighborhood of the 
steady profit rate R* does not change qualitatively the stability 
properties of the dynamical system as proposed in (10) and as 
reformulated in discrete time by (11). 
IV.l.2. Convergence of the Price-Quantity Dynamics - Model 2 
The additional adjustment term in the system (7) assumes that firms 
respond with their investment not only to the deviations of the profit 
rates from the natural or average value, but they also take into 
account the rate of change of profit rates when deciding on 
investments. System (7) can be rewritten by referring to the time rate 
of change as in system (7) as follows 
. 
x <d1><x>[(I-R*A) 'p + ~S(p)x] 
. (12) 
p 
System (12) suggests therefore the following discrete form for our 
iteration procedure. 
Xt + 1 Xt + <d1 ><Xt > [ (I-R* A) 'Pt + ~S (p) xt ] 
Pt+l Pt + <d2 ><Pt>(AR*- I)x 
(13) 
Taking into account the determination of S(p)Xt as proposed in 
section 2, the first part of the iteration (13) can be written as 
with 
Xt + <d1><xt>(I-R*A)'Pt + <dl><Xt>~s 
_<dl><Xt>~(I-R*A) '<d2 ><Pt>(I-AR*)Xt 
The average rate R(Xt'Pt) will also be used instead of the natural 
rate R* in the following. 
In the new iterative procedure, we use the same data for the matrix 
A as in section IV.l.l which means that the maximum eigenvalue and the 
associated eigenvectors are the same as before. The adjustment 
25 
coefficients d 1 , d 2 remain the same as in the model before. In 
addition, we use ~ = .5 as adjustment parameter for S(p)xt .

Continue navegando